THE ECONOMETRICS OF MACROECONOMIC MODELLING
Factorization
Finally, we shall take a look at this very elegant method introduced by Sargent. It consists of the following steps:
1. Write the model in terms of lead - and lag-polynomials in expectations.
2. Factor the polynomials, into one-order polynomials, deriving the roots.
3. Invert the factored one-order polynomials into the directions of converging forward polynomials of expectations.
Again, we use the simplifying definition
zt = bp2Xt + £pt:
so the model is again
Apt = bp1EtApt+i + bpiApt-i + zt.
Note that the forward, or lead, operator, F, and lag operator, L, only work on the variables and not expectations, so:
LEtzt = Etzt-i
FEtZt = Etzt+i L-i = F.
The model can then be written in terms of expectations as:
-bpiEtApt+i + EtApt - bpEApt-i = EtZt, and using the lead - and lag-operators:
(-bpiF + 1 — bpiL)EtApt = Etzt,
or, as a second-order polynomial in the lead operator:
The polynomial in brackets is exactly the same as the one in (A.12), so we know it can be factored into the roots (A.13):
However, we know that (1/1-(1/a2)F) = ^=0(1/a2)iFi, since |1/a2| < 1,
so we can write down the solution immediately:
where we have also substituted back for zt.
To derive the complete solution, we have to solve for
Etxt+i
given
(1 bXL)xt Єxt.
We can now appeal to the results of Sargent (1987, p. 304) that work as follows. If the model can be written in the form
yt = Etyt+- + xta(L)xt + et,
r
a(L) =1 -^2 aj L°
j=-
with the partial solution
yt = (A)i Et'xt+i,
i=o
1 - XL-[116] r — 1 a(X)—1 1 + £ Y, Xk—jau I Lj j=1 k=j+1 |
The solution therefore becomes Apt - a.1 Apt—1 = 1 |
o1^2 . |
then the complete solution
as before.