Springer Texts in Business and Economics

Simultaneous Equations Model

11.1 The Inconsistency of OLS. The OLS estimator from Eq. (11.14) yields 8ols =

T T

E Ptqt/ E Pt2 where pt = Pt — l3 and qt = Qt — Q. Substituting qt = 8pt C

t=i t=i

TT

(u2t — U2) from (11.14) we get 8ois = 8 C E Pt(u2t — N/Y, P2. Using (11.18),

t=i t=i

T

we get plim £ Pt(U2t — U2)/T = (012 — 022)/(8 — ") where Oij = cov. Uit, Ujt)

t=1

for i, j = 1,2 and t = 1,2,.., T. Using (11.20) we get

Plim 8ois = 8 C [(CT12 — 022)/(8 — ")]/[(011 C CT22 — 2ст12)/(8 — ")2] = 8 C (o12 — 022)(8 — ")/(o11 C 022 — 2°12).

11.2 When Is the IVEstimator Consistent?

a. ForEq.(11.30)y1 = a^y2 C '1зУз C "11X1 C "12X2 C U1.Whenweregress

T

У2 on X1, X2 and X3 to get У2 = у2 C V2, the residuals satisfy E y2tV2t = 0

t=1

TTT

and 22 V2tXu = 22 V2tX2t = 22 V2tX3t = 0.

t=1 t=1 t=1

Similarly, when we regress y3 on X1, X2 and X4 to get y3 = y3 C

T T T

V3, the residuals satisfy E y3t83t = 0 and E V3tXu = E ^3tX2t =

t=1 t=1 t=1

T

E v3tX4t = 0. In the second stage regression y1 = a^y2 C '13y3 C

t=1

"11X1 C "12X2 C £1 where Є1 = '12 (y2 — 382) C '13(y3 — 383) C u =

T

'12882 C'13883Cu1. For this to yield consistent estimates, we needE 2t©1t =

t=1

Ey^m E y3t©1t = E y3^; £ X1t£1t = E X1tu1t and E X2t£1t =

t=1 t=1 t=1 t=1 t=1 t=1

E X2tu1t. But E y 2t©1t = '12 E 882ty2t C '13 E 88 3t:8 2t C E y2tu1t with

t=1 t=1 t=1 t=1 t=1

T

E V2ty2t = 0 because 882 are the residuals and y2 are the Predicted val-

t=1

T

ues from the same regression. However, 883ty2t is not necessarily zero

t=1

B. H. Baltagi, Solutions Manual for Econometrics, SPringer Texts in Business and Economics, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-54548-1—11, © SPringer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2015

because V3 is only orthogonal to Xi, X2 and X4, while У2 is a perfect linear

T

combination of Xi, X2 and X3. Hence, Y $3tX3t is not necessarily zero,

t=i

T

which makes Y v3ty2t not necessarily zero.

t=i

T T T T

Similarly, y3t©it = ai2 £ V2ty3t C 'nY v3ty3t C Y y3tuit with

t=i t=i t=i t=i

TT

Y v3ty3t = 0 and Y V2ty^3t not necessarily zero. This is because V2t is

t=i t=i

only orthogonal to Xi, X2 and X3, while y3 is a perfect linear combina-

T

tion of Xi, X2 and X4. Hence, Y v2tX4t is not necessarily zero, which

t=i

T

makes Y V2ty3t not necessarily zero. Since both Xi and X2 are included

t=i

TT

in the first stage regressions, we have J]Xit£it = Y XitUit using the

t=i t=i

T T T T

fact that XitV2t = Y XitV3t = 0. Also, X2teit = Y X2tuit since

t=i t=i t=i t=i

TT

Y X2tV2t = Y X2tV3t = 0.

t=i t=i

b. The first stage regressions regress y2 and y3 on X2, X3 and X4 to get

T

y2 = y2 C V2 and y3 = y3 C V3 with the residuals satisfying Y V2ty2t =

t=i

Y V2tX2t = J2 V2tX3t = J2 V2tX4t = 0 and Y V3ty3t = J2 V3tX2t =

t=i t=i t=i t=i t=i

TT

v3tX3t = V v3tX4t = 0. In the second stage regression yi = ai2y2 C

t=i t=i

'i3y3 C PiiXi C "i2X2 C £i where ei = ап(у2 - У2) C ai3.y3 - У3) C ui = ai2v2 C ai3v3 C ui. For this to yield consistent estimates, we need p y2t©it = p y2tuit; p y3teit = p y3tuit; p X^it = p Xituit and

t=i t=i t=i t=i t=i t=i

P X2t©it = P X2tuit.

t=i t=i

The first two equalities are satisfied because

T T T T

y2tv2t = y2tv3t = 0 and y3tv2t = y3tv3t = 0

t=i t=i t=i t=i

since the same set of X’s are included in both first stage regressions.

T T T T

Y X2t©it = Y X2tuit because X2tV2t = Y X2tV3t = 0 since X2 is

t=i t=i t=i t=i

T T

included in both first-stage regressions. However, X1te1t ф X1tu1t

t=i t=i

TT

since y^X1tv2t ф 0 and E XitV3t ф 0

t=i t=i

because Xi was not included in the first stage regressions.

11.3 Just-Identification and Simple IV. If Eq. (11.34) is just-identified, then X2 is of the same dimension as Yi, i. e., both are Txgi. Hence, Zi is of the same dimension as X, both of dimension Tx (g1 + k1). Therefore, X0Z1 is a square non-singular matrix of dimension (g1 + k1). Hence, (ZjX) 1 exists. But from (11.36), we know that

•i,2SLS = (ZjPxZi)-1 ZjPxyi = [Z1X(X, X)-1X, Z1]“1 Z1X(X, X)-1X, y1

= (X, Z1)-1(X, X) (z;x)-1 (z;x) (x0x)-1x0y1 = (x0ZO-1x0y1

as required. This is exactly the IV estimator with W = X given in (11.41). It is important to emphasize that this is only feasible if X0Z1 is square and non-singular.

11.4 2SLS Can Be Obtained as GLS. Premultiplying (11.34) by X0 we get X0y1 = X, Z181 + X0u1 with X0u1 having mean zero and var(X0u1) = o11X0X since var(u1) = o11 IT. Performing GLS on this transformed equation yields

•i, gls = [Z01X(anX0X)-1X0Z1]-1Z01X(an X0X)-1X0y1 = (Z^Zi)-^0^

as required.

11.5 The Equivalence of 3SLS and 2SLS.

a. From (11.46), (i) if X is diagonal then X-1 is diagonal and X-1 <S> PX is block-diagonal with the i-th block consisting of PX/(tii. Also, Z is block - diagonal, therefore, fZ0[X-1 <S> PX]Z}-1 is block-diagonal with the i-th block consisting of (jii (Z0PXZ^ 1. In other words,

/Zi 0 .. o

0 Z2 .. 0

y0 0 .. Zoy

/ZiPXZi/CT11 0 .. 0

0 Z2 Px Z2 /f^22 .. 0

у 0 0 .. Z0PxZo/6ooy

VZ0Pxyo/ООО у

Hence, from (11.46) 83SLS = {Z0[C 1 <8> Px]Z} 1{Z0[^ 1 (g> Px]y}

(ii) If every equation in the system is just-identified, then ZiX is square and non-singular for i = 1,2, ..,G. In problem 11.3, we saw that for say the first equation, both Z1 and X have the same dimension Tx(g1 + k1). Hence, Z1X is square and of dimension (g1 + k1). This holds for every

equation of the just-identified system. In fact, problem 11.3 proved that 8il2SLS = (X, Zi)_1 X0yifori = 1,2,.., G. Also, from (11.44), we get

83SLS = {diag [Z0X] [t-1 ® (X0X)-1] diag [X0Zi]}-1

{diag [Z0X] [£-1 ® (X0X)-1] (Ig ® X0)y}.

But each Zi0X is square and non-singular, hence

83SLS = [diag (X'Zi)-1 (£ ® (X0X)) diag (Z0X)-1

{diag (Z0X) [e-1 ® (X0X)-1] (Ig ® X0)y}.

which upon cancellation yields

O3SLS = diag(X0Zi)-1 (Ig ® X0)y

/(X, Z1)-1 0 .. 0 1 0 X'yA

b. Premultiplying (11.43) by (IG <g> PX) yields y* = Z*8 + u* where y* = (IG <8>PX )y, Z* = (IG <S>PX )Zandu* = (IG <g>PX)u. OLS on this transformed model yields

Sols = (Z*0Z*)-1Z*0y* = [Z0(Ig ® Px)Z]-1 [Z0(Ig ® PX)y]

v 0 0

.. (ZG

0 (z;PxZ1)-1 ZjPXy1 1

*01,2SLS^

(z2PxZ2)-1 Z2PXy2

=

8 2,2SLS

V(ZGPxZg)-1 ZGPXyGyi

V8 G,2SLS /

which is the 2SLS estimator of each equation in (11.43). Note that u* has mean zero and var(u*) = £ <S> PX since var(u) = £ <S> IT. The generalized inverse of var(u*) is £-1 <S> PX. Hence, GLS on this transformed model yields

8gls = [Z*0(£-1 ® Px)Z*]-1Z*0(£-1 ® Px)y*

= [Z0(Ig <8> Px)(£ 1 <S> Px)(Ig <S> Px)Z] 1Z0(Ig <8> Px)(£ 1 <S> Px) x (Ig <S> Px)y

= [Z0(£-1 ® Px)Z]-1Z0[£-1 ® Px]y.

Using the Milliken and Albohali condition for the equivalence of OLS and GLS given in Eq. (9.7) of Chap. 9, we can obtain a necessary and sufficient condition for 2SLS to be equivalent to 3SLS. After all, the last two esti­mators are respectively OLS and GLS on the transformed * system. This condition gives Z*0(£-1 <S> PX)PZ* = 0 since Z* is the matrix of regres­sors and £ <S> PX is the corresponding variance-covariance matrix. Note that Z* = diag[PXZ0] = diag[Z0] or a block-diagonal matrix with the i-th block being the matrix of regressors of the second-stage regression of 2SLS. Also, PZ* = diag[PZ. ] andPZ* = diag[Pz]. Hence, the above condition reduces to оijZ0PZj = 0 for i ф j and i, j = 1,2,.., G.

If £ is diagonal, this automatically satisfies this condition since cry = оij=0 for i ф j. Also, if each equation in the system is just-identified, then Z0X and X0Zj are square and non-singular. Hence,

I0Z (z0j 1 Zj = Z0X(X0X)-1X0Zj ZjX(X0X)-1X0Zj 1

Z0X(X0X)-1X0 = Z0X(X0X)-1X0 = Z0PX = Z0

after some cancellations. Hence, Z0P = Z0 — Z0P = Z0 — Z0 = 0, under

0 Z 0 0 Z 0 0

just-identification of each equation in the system.

11.6 a. Writing this system of two equations in the matrix form given by (A.1) we

(?)

b. There are two zero restrictions on Г. These restrictions state that Wt and Lt do not appear in the demand equation. Therefore, the first equation is over­identified by the order condition of identification. There are two excluded exogenous variables and only one right hand side included endogenous vari­able. However, the supply equation is not identified by the order condition of identification. There are no excluded exogenous variables, but there is one right hand side included endogenous variable.

c. The transformed matrix FB should satisfy the following normalization restrictions: fll + fl2 = 1 and f2i + f22 = 1.

These are the same normalization restrictions given in (A.6). Also, Fr must satisfy the following zero restrictions:

f110 - f12e = 0 and f110 - f12f = 0.

If either e or f are different from zero, so that at least Wt or Lt appear in the supply equation, then f12 = 0. This means that f11 + 0 = 1 or f11 = 1, from the first normalization equation. Hence, the first row of F is indeed the first row of an identity matrix and the demand equation is identified. However, there are no zero restrictions on the second equation and in the absence of any additional restrictions f21 ф 0 and the second row of F is not necessarily the second row of an identity matrix. Hence, the supply equation is not identified.

11.7 a. In this case,

1

b

; Г =

-a - c

-d

0 0

1

-f

-e 0

0

-g - h

1,Yt, At

Wt, Lt]

and u(

= (u1t

,u2t).

B

I yt =

b. There are four zero restrictions on Г. These restrictions state that Yt and At are absent from the supply equation whereas Wt and Lt are absent from the demand equation. Therefore, both equations are over-identified. For each equation, there is one right hand sided included endogenous variable and two excluded exogenous variables.

c. The transformed matrix FB should satisfy the following normalization restrictions:

fll + fl2 = 1 and f2i + f22 = 1.

Also, Fr must satisfy the following zero restrictions:

—f21 c C f220 = 0 - f21 d + f220 = 0.

and

fii0 — f12g = 0 fii0 — f12h = 0.

If either c or d are different from zero, so that at least Yt or At appear in the demand equation, then f2i = 0 and from the second normalization equation we deduce that f22 = i. Hence, the second row of F is indeed the second row of an identity matrix and the supply equation is identified. Similarly, if either g or h are different from zero, so that at least Wt or Lt appear in the supply equation, then fi2 = 0 and from the first normalization equation we deduce that fii = i. Hence, the first row of F is indeed the first row of an identity matrix and the demand equation is identified.

11.8 a. From example (A.1) and Eq. (A.5), we get

i b —a —c 0

i —e —d 0 —f

Therefore, ® for the first equation consists of only one restriction, namely that Wt is not in that equation, or yi3 = 0. This makes ф0 = (0,0,0,0, i), since

'ф = 0 gives уїз = 0. Therefore,

**=0=(.”,).

This is of rank one as long as f ф 0. Similarly, for * the second equation consists of only one restriction, namely that Yt is not in that equation, or У22 = 0. This makes * = (0,0,0,1,0/, since al* = 0 gives у22 = 0. 'У 12 I

/(e + b).

This can be easily verified by solving the two equations in (A.3) and (A.4) for Pt and Qt in terms of the constant, Yt and Wt.

From part (a) and Eq. (A.17), we can show that the parameters of the first structural equation can be obtained from al [W, *] = 0 where '1 = ("11, "12, "її, у12, уїз) represents the parameters of the first structural equation. W0 = [П, I3] and *0 = (0,0,0,0,1) as seen in part (a).

"11^11 + "12^21 + У11 = 0 "11^12 + "12^22 + У12 = 0 "11^13 + "12^23 + У13 = 0 у1з = 0

If we normalize by setting "11 = 1, we get "12 = —л13/л23 also

Л13 л22л13 — л12л23

У12 = —12 H---------------- Л22 = ---------------------------------- and

Л23 Л23

Л13 ТС21Л13 — ли Л23

У11 = — л11 H---------------- л21 = ------------------------------------ .

л23 л23

One can easily verify from the reduced form parameters that "12 = - Л13/Н23 = - bf/ — f = b.

Similarly, "12 = (л 22 л 13 - л 12 л 23)/ Л23 = (cbf + ecf)/ - f(e + b) = - c. Finally, "її = (л 2i л із - лїї л23)/ л 23 = (abf + aef)/ - f(e + b) = - a. Similarly, for the second structural equation, we get,

л 11

12

13

0

л 21

22

23

0

("21, "22, "2b "22, "23)

61

0

0

0

= (0, 0, 0, 0, 0)

0

1

0

1

0

0

1

0

which can be rewritten

as

"21 л 11 + "22 л 21 + "21

=0

"21 л 12 + "22 л 22 + "22

=0

"21 л 13 + "22 л 23 + "23

=0

"22

= 0.

If we normalize by setting "21 = 1, we get "22 = — л 12/ л 22 also

л 12 л 23л 12 - л 13л 22 ,

"23 = - л13 Н---------------- л 23 = ---------------------------------- and

22 22

л 12 л12 л 21 - л 11 л 22

"21 = — л11 Н---------------- л 21 = ----------------------------------- .

22 22

One can easily verify from the reduced form parameters that "22 = - л 12/ л 22 = - ec/c = - e. Similarly,

"23 = (л 23л 13 - л 13л 22)/ л 22 = (-ecf - bdf)/c(e + b) = - f. Finally, "21 = (л 12 л 21 - лпл 22)/ л 22 = (-dec - bdc)/c(e + b) = - d.

11.9 For the simultaneous model in problem 11.6, the reduced form parameters

are given

11

12

13

ab C bc

be

bf

21

22

23

a - c

-e

-f

by

/(b C d)

This can be easily verified by solving for Pt and Qt in terms of the constant, Wt and Lt. From the solution to 11.6, we get

A = [B, Г] =

For the first structural equation,

0

0

0

0

0

0

1

0

0

1

Ф =

with ' ф

= 0 yielding

"12 =

"13 =

= 0. Therefore, (A.17) reduces to

т 11

12

т 13

0

0

т 21

22

23

0

0

("11, "12

"11, "12, "13)

1

0

0

0

0

= (0, 0, 0, 0, 0)

60

1

0

1

0

0

0

1

0

1

This can be rewritten as

"іітс її + Р12Л 21 + "її = 0 "11 те 12 + Р12Л 22 + "12 = 0 "її те 13 + Р12Л 23 + "13 = 0 "12 = 0 "13 = 0

If we normalize by setting "11 = 1,weget"12 = — тт13/тт23; "12 = — т 12/ тт22.

Also, "11 = — ти + (^12/^22)^21 =

(т 13/ тт23)тт21 = —21—13-------------------- 11—23 one can easily verify from the reduced form

23

parameters that

"12 = - т 13/T23 = - bf/ — f = b. Also "12 = — т 12/т22 = —be/ — e = b. Similarly,

Also,

n 21n 13 — n 11n 23 abf — bcf + adf + bcf a(bf + df)

Y11 n 23 —f(b + d) —(bf + df) a

For the second structural equation there are no zero restrictions. Therefore, (A.15) reduces to

(0,0,0,0,0)

This can be rewritten as

"21n 11 + "22n 21 + "21 = 0 "21n 12 + "22 n 22 + "22 = 0

"21 n 13 + "22 n 23 + "23 = 0

Three equations in five unknowns. When we normalize by setting "21 = 1, we still get three equations in four unknowns for which there is no unique solution.

11.10 Just-Identified Model.

a. The generalized instrumental variable estimator for 81 based on W is given below (11.41)

8Uv = (Z^wZ!)-1 ZiPWy!

Z1W (w0w) 1 W0 Z1

= (W0Z1)—!(W0W) (ZiW 1 (ZiW (W0W)—!W—1y1 = (W0 Z1)—1W0y1

since W0Z1 is square and non-singular under just-identification. This is exactly the expression for the simple instrumental variable estimator for 81 given in (11.38).

b. Let the minimized value of the criterion function be

Q = (yi — Zi8i, iv),Pw(Yi — Z18 i, iv).

Substituting the expression for 81jv and expanding terms, we get

Q = yiPWy1 — yiW (ZiW)-1 ZiPWy1 — yiPWZ1(W, Zi)-1W, yi + y1W (Z1W)-1 Z1 PwZ 1 ( W0Z1)-1 W0y 1 Q = y,1PWy1 — y1W (Z1W)-1 Z,1W(W, W)-1 W0y1 — y'^^W/^W^ (W,1Z1)-1 W0y1 + y1W (Z1W)-1 Z,1W(W/W)-1W0Z1(W, Z1)-1W, y1 Q = y1Pwy1 — y1Pwy1 — y1Pwy1 + y1Pwy1 = 0

as required.

c. Let Z1 = PWZ1 be the set of second stage regressors obtained from regress­ing each variable in Z1 on the set of instrumental variables W. For the just-identified case

PZ1 = PpwZ1 = Z1 (Z1Z1)- Z1 = PwZ1 (Z1PWZ1)-1 Z1Pw

= W(W0W)-1W0 Z1 [Z,1W(W, W)-1 W0 Z1]-1 Z-1W(W0W)-1W0 = W(W0W)-1W0Z1(W0Z1)-1(W0W) (Z,1W)-1 Z,1W(W0W)-1W0 = W(W0W)-1W0 = PW.

Hence, the residual sum of squares of the second stage regression for the just-identified model, yields y1P£ y1 = y1PWy1 since P% = PW. This is exactly the residual sum of squares from regression y1 on the matrix of instruments W.

11.11 The More Valid Instruments the Better. If the set of instruments W1 is spanned by the space of the set of instruments W2, then PW2Wi = W1. The corresponding two instrumental variables estimators are

with asymptotic covariance matrices cm plim (Z,1PwiZ1/T)_1 fori = 1,2.

The difference between the asymptotic covariance matrix of 81,w1 and that of 8i, w2 is positive semi-definite if

is positive semi-definite. This holds, if Z,1PW2Z1 — Z,1PW1Z1 is positive semi­definite. To show this, we prove that PW2 — PW1 is idempotent.

(Pw2 — Pw1 )(Pw2 — Pw1 ) = Pw2 — Pw2Pw1 — Pw1Pw2 + Pw1

= PW2 — PW1 — PW1 + PW1 = PW2 — PW1.

This uses the fact that PW2PW1 = PW2W1 (W'W1) 1 W' = W1 (W'W1) 1 W1 = Pw1, since PW2W1 = W1.

11.12 Testing for Over-Identification. The main point here is that W spans the same space as [Z 1,W*] and that both are of full rank '. In fact, W* is a subset of instruments W, of dimension (' — k1 — g1), that are linearly independent of Z1 = PwZ1.

a. Using instruments W, the second stage regression on y1 = Z181+W*y+u1 regresses y1 on PW[Z1,W*] = [Z 1,W*] since Z 1 = PWZ1 and W* = PWW*. But the matrix of instruments W is of the same dimension as the matrix of regressors [Z 1,W*]. Hence, this equation is just-identified, and from problem 11.10, we deduce that the residual sum of squares of this second stage regression is exactly the residual sum of squares obtained by regressing y1 on the matrix of instruments W, i. e.,

URSS* = yjPwy1 = yiy1 — yiPwy1.

b. Using instruments W, the second stage regression on y1 = Z181 + u1

regresses y1 on Z 1 = PWZ1. Hence, the RRSS* = y,1P21 y1 = y1y1 — y,1Pz 1 y1 where P^ = I — 1 and P^ = Z1 (^Z1) Z1 =

PWZ1 (Z,1PWZ1) 1 Z'jPw. Therefore, using the results in part (a) we get RRSS* - URSS* = y,1PWy1 - ylPZiy1 as given in (11.49).

c. Hausman (1983) proposed regressing the 2SLS residuals (y1 — Z1812SLS) on the set of instruments W and obtaining nR^ where R is the uncentered R2 of this regression. Note that the regression sum of squares yields

(y1 — Z1Q1,2sls )0Pw(y1 — Z1§1,2SLs)

= y1PWy1 — y,1PWZ1(Z,1PWZ1)_1Z,1PWy1 — y,1PWZ1(Z,1PWZ1)_1Z,1PWy1 + y,1PWZ1(Z1PWZ1)-1Z,1PWZ1 (z;PwZ1)“1 Z1PWy1 = y1Pwy1 — y1PwZ1 (Z^PwZ1) 1 Z1Pwy1 = y,1PWy1 — yiPZl y1 = RRSS* — URSS*

as given in part (b). The total sum of squares of this regression, uncentered, is the 2SLS residuals sum of squares given by

(y1 — Z1Q1,2sls )0(y1 — Z1Q1,2SLs) = T5n

where an is given in (11.50). Hence, the test statistic

RRSS* — URSS* Regression Sum of Squares

&П Uncentered Total Sum of Squares / T

= T(uncentered R2) = T R2 as required.

This is asymptotically distributed as x2 with ' — (g1 + k1) degrees of freedom. Large values of this test statistic reject the null hypothesis.

d. The GNR for the unrestricted model given in (11.47) computes the resid­uals from the restricted model under Ho; " = 0. These are the 2SLS residuals (y1 — Z1q12SLS) based on the set of instruments W. Next, one differentiates the model with respect to its parameters and evaluates these derivatives at the restricted estimates. For instrumental variables W one has to premultiply the right hand side of the GNR by PW, this yields (yi - Zi81,2sls) = PWZ1b1 + PWW*b2 + residuals.

But Z1 = PWZ1 and PWW* = W* since W* is a subset of W. Hence, the GNR becomes (y1 — Z181,2SLS) = Z 1b1 + W*b2 + residuals. How­ever, [Z1, W*] spans the same space as W, see part (a). Hence, this GNR regresses 2SLS residuals on the matrix of instruments W and computes TR where Ru is the uncentered R2 of this regression. This is Hausman’s (1983) test statistic derived in part (c).

11.15 a. The artificial regression in (11.55) is given by

y 1 = Z181 + (Y1 — Y1)^ + residuals

This can be rewritten as y1 = Z181 + IіWY1q + residuals where we made use of the fact that Y1 = PWY1 with Y1 — Y1 = Y1 — PWY1 = IіWY1. Note that to residual out the matrix of regressors PWY1, we need

P pwy1 = I — PwY1(Y1PwY1)-1Y1Pw

so that, by the FWL Theorem, the OLS estimate of 81 can also be obtained from the following regression

P PwY1 y1 = P PwY1 Z181 + residuals.

Note that

Ppwy1 Z1 = Z1 — PwY1(Y1PwY1)-1Y1 PwZ1

with PWZ1 = [PWY1,0] and PWX1 = 0 since X1 is part of the instruments in W. Hence, PpwY1 Z1 = [Y1,X1] — [PwY1,0] = [PWY1,X1] = [Y1 ,X1] = Pw[Y1,X1] = PwZi = Z1 In this case,

8l, ols = (Z1PpwY1Z1)-1 Z1PPWY1 y1 = (Z1Z1)- ^ 1y1

= (Z1PwZ1) 1 Z1Pwy1 = 8 1,iv as required.

b. The FWL Theorem also states that the residuals from the regressions in part (a) are the same. Hence, their residuals sum of squares are the same. The last regression computes an estimate of the var(81,ojs) as s2 (Z^PwZ^ 1 where s2 is the residual sum of squares divided by the degrees of freedom of the regression. In (11.55), this is the MSE of that regression, since it has the same residuals sum of squares. Note that when r ф 0 in (11.55), IV estimation is necessary and s11 underestimates o11 and will have to be replaced by

(y1 — Z181,Iy),(y1 — Z1§1,iv)/T.

11.16 Recursive Systems.

a. The order condition of identification yields one excluded exogenous vari­able (x3) from the first equation and no right hand side endogenous variable i. e., k2 = 1 andg1 = 0. Therefore, the first equation is over-identified with degree of over-identification equal to one. The second equation has two excluded exogenous variables (x1 and x2) and one right hand side endoge­nous variable (y1) so that k2 = 2 and g1 = 1. Hence, the second equation is over-identified of degree one. The rank condition of identification can be based on

"12 0

0 "23_

(x1t, x2t, x3t). For the first equation, the set of

where ' is the first row of A. For the second equation, the set of zero restrictions yield

where a2 is the second row of A. Hence, for the first equation

which is of rank 1 in general. Hence, the first equation is identified by the rank condition of identification. Similarly, for the second equation

"11 "12 0 0

which is of rank 1 as long as either "11 or "12 are different from zero. This ensures that either x1 or x2 appear in the first equation to identify the second equation.

b. The first equation is already in reduced form format y1t — —"lix1t - "I2x2t + u1t

y1t is a function of x1t, x2t and only u1t, not u2t. For the second equation, one can substitute for y1t to get

y2t — -"23x3t — "21 (—"11 x1t — "I2x2t + u1t) + u2t

— "21"11x1t + "21" 12x2t - "23x3t + u2t - "21 u1t

so that y2t is a function of x1t, x2t, x3t and the error is a linear combination of u1t and u2t.

c. OLS on the first structural equation is also OLS on the first reduced form equation with only exogenous variables on the right hand side. Since x1 and x2 are not correlated with u1t, this yields consistent estimates for "11
and y12. OLS on the second equation regresses y2t on y1t and x3t. Since x3t is not correlated with u2t, the only possible correlation is from y1t and u2t. However, from the first reduced form equation y1t is only a function of exogenous variables and u1t. Since u1t and u2t are not correlated because £ is diagonal for a recursive system, OLS estimates of "21 and y23 are consistent.

d. Assuming that ut ~ N(0, £) where u( = (u1t, u2t), this exercise shows that OLS is MLE for this recursive system. Conditional on the set of x’s, the likelihood function is given by

L(B, Г, £) = (2 Tt)-T/2|B|T|£|-T/2 exp(-2 £u0£-1utj so that

1 T

logL = -(T/2) log2 к + Tlog |B| - (T/2) log |£| - ^ ^u0£ 1ut.

2 t=1

Since B is triangular, |B| = 1 so that log |B| = 0. Therefore, the only place

T

in logL where B and Г parameters appear is in u0£-1ut. Maximizing

t=1

T

logL with respect to B and Г is equivalent to minimizing ^ u0£-1ut with

t=1

respect to B and Г. But £ is diagonal, so £-1 is diagonal and

T T T

£u0£-4 = J2 u2t/CT11 + £ u2‘/CT22.

t=1 t=1 t=1

The partial derivatives of logL with respect to the coefficients of the first

T

structural equation are simply the partial derivatives of J^u2t/on with

t=1

respect to those coefficients. Setting these partial derivatives equal to zero yields the OLS estimates of the first structural equation. Similarly, the partial derivatives of logL with respects to the coefficients of the second

T

structural equation are simply the derivatives of u22t/o22 with respect to

t=1

those coefficients. Setting these partial derivatives equal to zero yields the OLS estimates of the second structural equation. Hence, MLE is equivalent to OLS for a recursive system.

11.17 Hausman s Specification Test: 2SLS Versus 3SLS. This is based on Baltagi (1989).

a. The two equations model considered is

yi = Z181 + ui and y2 = Z282 + u2 (1)

where yi and y2 are endogenous; Z1 = [y2,x1,x2], Z2 = [y1,x3]; and x1, x2 and x3 are exogenous (the y’s and x’s are Tx1 vectors). As noted in the problem, 8 = 2SLS, 8 = 3SLS, and the corresponding residuals are denoted by u and u. = (a, "1, "2) and 82 = (у, "3) with ay ф 1,so that

the system is complete and we can solve for the reduced form.

Let X = [x1,x2,x3] and PX = X(X0X)_1X0, the 3SLS equations for model (1) are given by

Z0 (Ё_1 <S> Px) ZQ = Z0 (Ё_1 <S> Px) y (2)

where Z = diag[Zi], y0 = (y1,y2), and Ё_1 = [(8ij] is the inverse of the estimated variance-covariance matrix obtained from 2SLS residuals. Equation (2) can also be written as

Z (Ё_1 <S> Px) u = 0, (3)

or more explicitly as

511Z,1Px^ 1 +1812Z11Pxu2 = 0 (4)

512Z2Pxu 1 C 522Z2Pxu2 = 0 (5)

Using the fact that Z1X is a square non-singular matrix, one can premulti­ply (4) by (X0X) (Z01X)“1 to get

511X0ti 1 C cr12X0ti2 = 0. (6)

b. Writing Eq. (5) and (6) in terms of Q1 and Q2, one gets

512 (Z2PxZ1) 81 C 522 (Z2PxZ2) 82 = 512 (Z2PxyO C (822 (Z2Pxy2) (7)
and

511X, ZiQi C &12X0Z28l2 = 511X, yi C 812X0y2. (8)

Premultiply (8) by 512Z'2X(X'X)~1 and subtract it from 511 times (7). This eliminates 81, and solves for 82:

82 = (Z2PxZ2)_1 Z2PXy2 = 82. (9)

Therefore, the 3SLS estimator of the over-identified equation is equal to its 2SLS counterpart.

Substituting (9) into (8), and rearranging terms, one gets 511X, Z1Q1 = 511X0y1 +512X0u2.

Premultiplying by Z,1X(X, X)_1/511, and solving for 81, one gets Q1 = (Z'^xZ!)-1 Z1Pxy1 C (512/511) (ZjPxZi)"1 ZjPxu. (10)

Using the fact that 512 = — 512/|£|, and 511 = 522/|£|, (10) becomes 81 = 81 — (512 /522) (Z'iPxZi)"1 Z'iPxu2. 01

Therefore, the 3SLS estimator of the just-identified equation differs from its 2SLS (or indirect least squares) counterpart by a linear combination of the 2SLS (or 3SLS) residuals of the over-identified equation; see Theil (1971).

c. A Hausman-type test based on and is given by

m = (Qi —81)0 [v (81) — v (81)] 1 (8i — Qi)

where V(8') = 5n (Z'PxZi) 1

and V(8i) = (1/5'') (Z'PxZi)-1 C (^/o^) (Z'PxZi)"1

(Z'iPXZ2) (Z2PxZ2)-1 (Z2PxZi) (Z'PxZi)"1 .

The latter term is obtained by using the partitioned inverse of Z0(£"' <S>

PX)Z. Using (11), the Hausman test statistic becomes m = (5i22/5222) (u2PxZi) [(5ii — 1/5n) (Z'iPxZi)

— (5i22/522) (Z'iPxZ2) (Z2PxZ2)-1 (Z2PxZi)]-1 (Z'iPxu2) .

However, (on — 1/(7n) = (@12І®22); this enables us to write

where Zi = PXZi is the matrix of second stage regressors of 2SLS, for i = 1,2. This statistic is asymptotically distributed as /J, and can be given the following interpretation:

Claim: m = TR2, where R2 is the R-squared of the regression of u2 on the set of second stage regressors of both equations, Z1 and Z2.

Proof. This result follows immediately using the fact that cr22 =

u2u2/T = total sums of squares/T, and the fact that the regression sum of squares is given by

where the last equality follows from partitioned inverse and the fact that

Z 2u 2 = o.

11.18 a. Using the order condition of identification, the first equation has two excluded exogenous variables x2 and x3 and only one right hand sided included endogenous variable y2. Hence,

k2 = 2 > g1 = 1

with yt = (y1t, y2t) and xt = (x1t, x2t, x3t). The first structural equation has the following zero restrictions:

where 'і is the first row of A. Similarly, the second structural equation has the following zero restriction:

where a2 is the second row of A. Hence, A¥1 = which has

"22 "2з

rank one provided either "22 or "23 is different from zero. Similarly, A¥2 = /"11

0

identified by the rank condition of identification. b. For the first equation, the OLS normal equations are given by

(ЗДІ “12 = Z1y1

V"" 1V ols

where Z1 = [y2,x1]. Hence,

Z1Z1

obtained from the matrices of cross-products provided by problem 11.18.

Hence, the OLS normal equations are

8 1^/p 12 10 20j "и

solving for the OLS estimators, we get

OLS on the second structural equation can be deduced in a similar fashion.

c. For the first equation, the 2SLS normal equations are given by

where Z' = [y2,x1] andX = [x1,x2,x3]. Hence, Z'X =

with

Therefore, the 2SLS normal equations are

2SLS on the second structural equation can be deduced in a similar fashion.

d. The first equation is over-identified and the reduced form parameter esti­mates will give more than one solution to the structural form parameters.

However, the second equation is just-identified. Hence, 2SLS reduces to indirect least squares which in this case solves uniquely for the structural parameters from the reduced form parameters. ILS on the second equation yields

" 21

"22 = (X, Zi)-1X, y2

V23 ILS

where Z1 = [y1,x2,x3] andX = [x1,x2,x3]. Therefore,

and

'x'^

10

X0y2 =

x2y2

x03y2

=

20C

30

so that

" 21

5

0

0

-1

10

" 22

=

40

20

0

20C

" 23

ILS

20

0

10

30

Note that X0Z1 for the first equation is of dimension 3 x 2 and is not even square.

11.19 Supply and Demand Equations for Traded Money. This is based on Laffer (1970).

b. OLS Estimation

SYSLIN Procedure
Ordinary Least Squares Estimation

Model: SUPPLY Dependent variable: LNTM_P

Analysis of Variance

Sum of

Mean

Source

DF

Squares

Square

F Value

Prob>F

Model

2

0.28682

0.14341

152.350

0.0001

Error

18

0.01694

0.00094

C Total

20

0.30377

Root MSE 0.03068 R-Square 0.9442

DepMean 5.48051 Adj R-SQ 0.9380

C. V. 0.55982

Parameter Estimates

Variable

DF

Parameter

Estimate

Standard

Error

T for HO: Parameter=0

Prob > |T|

INTERCEP

1

3.661183

0.272547

13.433

0.0001

LNRM. P

1

0.553762

0.089883

6.161

0.0001

LNI

1

0.165917

0.012546

13.225

0.0001

OLS ESTIMATION OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION
SYSLIN Procedure
Ordinary Least Squares Estimation

Model: DEMAND Dependent variable: LNTM. P

Analysis of Variance

Sum of

Mean

Source

DF

Squares

Square

F Value

Prob>F

Model

4

0.29889

0.07472

245.207

0.0001

Error

16

0.00488

0.00030

C Total

20

0.30377

Root MSE 0.01746 R-Square

0.9839

Dep

Mean 5.48051 Adj R-SQ

0.9799

C. V.

0.31852

Parameter Estimates

Parameter

Standard

T for HO:

Variable

DF

Estimate

Error Parameter=0

Prob > |T|

INTERCEP

1

3.055597

0.647464

4.719

0.0002

LNY_P

1

0.618770

0.055422

11.165

0.0001

LNI

1

-0.015724

0.021951

-0.716

0.4841

LNS1

1

-0.305535

0.101837

-3.000

0.0085

LNS2

1

0.147360

0.202409

0.728

0.4771

c. 2SLS Estimation

SYSLIN Procedure
Two-Stage Least Squares Estimation

Model: SUPPLY Dependent variable: LNTM. P

Analysis of Variance

Sum of

Mean

Source

DF

Squares

Square

F Value

Prob>F

Model

2

0.29742

0.14871

150.530

0.0001

Error

18

0.01778

0.00099

C Total

20

0.30377

RootMSE 0.03143 R-Square

0.9436

Dep

Mean 5.48051 Adj R-SQ

0.9373

C. V.

0.57350

Parameter Estimates

Parameter

Standard

T for HO:

Variable

DF

Estimate

Error Parameter=0

Prob > |T|

INTERCEP

1

3.741721

0.280279

13.350

0.0001

LNRM. P

1

0.524645

0.092504

5.672

0.0001

LNI

1

0.177757

0.013347

13.318

0.0001

Test for OveridentifyingRestrictions

Numerator:

0.001342

DF: 2

F Value:

1.4224

Denominator:

0.000944

DF: 16

Prob>F:

0.2700

2SLS ESTIMATION OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION
SYSLIN Procedure
Two-Stage Least Squares Estimation

Model: DEMAND

Dependent variable: LNTM. P

Analysis of Variance

Sum of

Mean

Source

DF

Squares

Square

F Value

Prob>F

Model

4

0.30010

0.07503

154.837

0.0001

Error

16

0.00775

0.00048

C Total

20

0.30377

Root MSE 0.02201 R-Square 0.9748

Dep Mean 5.48051 Adj R-SQ 0.9685

C. V. 0.40165

Parameter Estimates

Variable

DF

Parameter

Estimate

Standard

Error

T for HO: Parameter=0

Prob > |T|

INTERCEP

1

1.559954

1.222958

1.276

0.2203

LNY_P

1

0.761774

0.111639

6.824

0.0001

LNI

1

-0.083170

0.049518

-1.680

0.1125

LNS1

1

-0.187052

0.147285

-1.270

0.2222

LNS2

1

0.228561

0.259976

0.879

0.3923

The total number of instruments equals the number of parameters in the equation. The equation is just identified, and the test for over identification is not computed.

d. 3 SLS Estimation

SYSLIN Procedure

Three-Stage Least Squares Estimation
Cross Model Covariance

Sigma SUPPLY DEMAND

SUPPLY 0.0009879044 -0.000199017

DEMAND -0.000199017 0.000484546

Cross Model Covariance

Corr SUPPLY DEMAND

SUPPLY 1 -0.287650003

DEMAND -0.287650003 1

Cross Model Inverse Correlation

Inv Corr

SUPPLY

DEMAND

SUPPLY

1.0902064321

0.3135978834

DEMAND

0.3135978834

1.0902064321

Cross Model Inverse Covariance

Inv Sigma

SUPPLY

DEMAND

SUPPLY

1103.5545963

453.26080422

DEMAND

453.26080422

2249.9545257

System Weighted MSE: 0.53916 with 34 degrees of freedom. System Weighted R-Square: 0.9858 Model: SUPPLY Dependent variable: LNTM. P

3SLS ESTIMATION OF MODEY SUPPLY AND DEMAND FUNCTION

SYSLIN Procedure

Three-Stage Least Squares Estimation
Parameter Estimates

Variable

DF

Parameter

Estimate

Standard

Error

T for HO: Parameter=0

Prob > |T|

INTERCEP

1

3.741721

0.280279

13.350

0.0001

LNRM. P

1

0.524645

0.092504

5.672

0.0001

LNI

1

0.177757

0.013347

13.318

0.0001

Model: DEMAND
Dependent variable: LNTM. P

Parameter Estimates

Variable

DF

Parameter

Estimate

Standard

Error

T for HO: Parameter=0

Prob > |T|

INTERCEP

1

1.887370

1.186847

1.590

0.1313

LNY_P

1

0.764657

0.110168

6.941

0.0001

LNI

1

-0.077564

0.048797

-1.590

0.1315

LNS1

1

-0.234061

0.141070

-1.659

0.1165

LNS2

1

0.126953

0.250346

0.507

0.6190

e. HAUSMANTEST

Hausman Test

2SLS vs OLS for SUPPLY Equation

HAUSMAN

6.7586205

2SLS vs OLS for DEMAND Equation

HAUSMAN

2.3088302

SAS PROGRAM

Data Laffer1; Input TM RM Y S2 i S1 P; Cards;

Data Laffer; Set Laffer1;

LNTM_P=LOG(TM/P);

LNRM_P=LOG(RM/P);

LNi=LOG(i);

LNY_P=LOG(Y/P);

LNS1=LOG(S1);

LNS2=LOG(S2);

T=21;

Proc syslin data=Lafferoutest=ols_s outcov;

SUPPLY: MODEL LNTM_P=LNRM_P LNi;

TITLE ‘OLS ESTIMATION OF MONEY SUPPLY FUNCTION’;

Proc syslin data=Lafferoutest=ols_s outcov;

DEMAND: MODEL LNTM_P=LNY_P LNi LNS1 LNS2;

TITLE ‘OLS ESTIMATION OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION’;

Proc syslin 2SLS data=Lafferoutest=TSLS_s outcov;

ENDO LNTMP LNi;

INST LNRM_P LNY_P LNS1 LNS2;

SUPPLY: MODEL LNTM_P=LNRM_P LNi/overid;

TITLE ‘2SLS ESTIMATION OF MONEY SUPPLY FUNCTION’;

Proc syslin 2SLS data=Lafferoutest=TSLS_d outcov;

ENDO LNTM_P LNi;

INST LNRM_P LNY_P LNS1 LNS2;

DEMAND: MODEL LNTM_P=LNY_P LNi LNS1 LNS2/overid; TITLE ‘2SLS ESTIMATION OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION’;

Proc SYSLIN 3SLS data=Lafferoutest=S_3SLS outcov; ENDO LNTMP LNi;

INST LNRM_P LNY_P LNS1 LNS2;

SUPPLY: MODEL LNTM_P=LNRM_P LNi;

DEMAND: MODEL LNTM_P=LNY_P LNi LNS1 LNS2; TITLE ‘3SLS ESTIMATION’;

RUN;

PROCIML;

TITLE ‘HAUSMAN TEST’;

use ols_s; read all var fintercep lnrm_p ini) into olsl;

olsbLs=ols1[1,]; ols_v_s=ols1[2:4,];

use ols_d; read all var f intercep lny_p lni lnsl lns2) into

ols2;

olsbLd=ols2[1,]; ols_v_d=ols2[2:6,];

use tsls_s; read all var f intercep lnrm_p lni} into tsls1;

tslsbts=tsls1[13,]; tsls_v_s=tsls1[14:16,];

use tsls_d; read all var f intercep lny_p lni lns1 lns2} into

tsls2;

tslsbtd=tsls2[13,]; tsls_v_d=tsls2[14:18,];

d=tslsbts ‘-olsbt_s‘; varcov=tsls_v_s-ols_v_s;

Hausman=d ‘*inv(varcov)*d;

print ‘Hauman Test’,, ‘2SLS vs OLS for SUPPLY Equation’,,

Hausman;

d=tslsbt_d ‘-olsbt_d‘; varcov=tsls_v_d-ols_v_d;

Hausman=d ‘*inv(varcov)*d;

print ‘2SLS vs OLS for DEMAND Equation’,, Hausman;

11.20 a. Writing this system of two equations in matrix form, as described in (A.1)

we get

xt = [1,Xt] and u0 = (u1t, u2t).

There are no zero restrictions for the demand equation and only one zero restriction for the supply equation (Xt does not appear in the supply equation). Therefore, the demand equation is not identified by the order condition since the number of excluded exogenous variables k2 = 0 is less than the number of right hand side included endogenous variables g1 = 1 .

Similarly, the supply equation is just-identified by the order condition since k2 = gi = 1.

By the rank condition, only the supply equation need be checked for identification. In this case, ф0 = (0,1/ since y22 = 0. Therefore,

Аф = Р’гіф = ("22) = (?).

This is of rank one as long as a2 ф 0, i. e., as long as Xt is present in the demand equation. One can also premultiply this system of two equations by

F = fi1 fi2 f21 f22

the transformed matrix FB should satisfy the following normalization restrictions: f11 + f12 = 1 and f21 + f22 = 1.

Also, Fr must satisfy the following zero restriction:

—«2f21 + 0 f22 = 0.

If a2 ф 0, then f21 = 0 which also gives from the second normalization equation that f22 = 1. Hence, the second row of F is indeed the second row of an identity matrix and the supply equation is identified. However, for the demand equation, the only restriction is the normalization restriction f11 + f12 = 1 which is not enough for identification.

„ T T

b. The OLS estimator of the supply equation yields " 1ols = J2 ptqt/ J2 p2

t=1 t=1

where pt = Pt — l5 and qt = Qt — Q. Substituting qt = "1 pt + (u2t — u2/

TT

we get " 1,ols = "1 + J2 pt(u2t — 7)/ E pj2.

t=1 t=1

« "o '2

The reduced form equation for Pt yields Pt = ------------------------------ ——------------ Xt +

uit — u2t «1 + "1

T

Defining mxx = plim J2 x2/T, we get

b. Regress yi and y3 on all the X’s including the constant, i. e., [1,Xi, X2,X5]. Get y i andy 3 and regress y2 on a constant, y 1, y 3 andX2 in the second-step regression.

c. For the first equation, regressing y2 on X2 and X3 yields

y2 — ft21 C ft22X2 + O23X3 C 'V2 — y2 + 'O2 T T T

with £ v2t — J2 v2tX2t — J2 v2tX3t — 0 by the property of least squares.

t=i t=i t=i

Replacing y2 by y2 in Eq. (1) yields yi — ai C "2 (y2 C v^2) C "iXi C ui — ai C "2y2 C "iXi C ("2v2 C ui) .

T

In this case, y2tv2t — 0 because the predictors and residuals of the same

t=i

T

regression are uncorrelated. Also, y2tu1t — 0 since y2t is a linear com-

t=i

T

bination of X2 and X3 and the latter are exogenous. However, X1tv2t

t=i

is not necessarily zero since Xi was not included in the first stage regres­sion. Hence, this estimation method does not necessarily lead to consistent estimates.

d. The test for over-identification for Eq. (1) can be obtained from the F-test given in Eq. (11.48) with RRSS* obtained from the second stage regres­sion residual sum of squares of 2SLS run on Eq. (1), i. e., the regression of yi on [i,^2,Xi] where y2 is obtained from the regression of y2 on [i, X1, X2.., X5]. The URSS* is obtained from the residual sum of squares of the regression of yi on all the set of instruments, i. e., [i, X1,.., X5]. The URSS is the 2SLS residual sum of squares of Eq. (1) as reported from any 2SLS package. This is obtained as

2

Note that this differs from RRSS* in that y2t and not y2t is used in the computation of the residuals. ', the number of instruments is 6 and ki — 2 while gi — i. Hence, the numerator degrees of freedom of the F-test is
' — (gi + ki) = 3 whereas the denominator degrees of freedom of the F-test isT — ' = T — 6. This is equivalent to running 2SLS residuals on the matrix of all predetermined variables [1 ,X1,.., X5] and computing T times the uncentered R2 of this regression. This is asymptotically distributed as X2 with three degrees of freedom. Large values of this statistic reject the over-identification restrictions.

11.23 Identification and Estimation of a Simple Two-Equation Model. This solution is based upon Singh and Bhat (1988).

®12

®12 m2

The structural and reduced form parameters are related as follows:

1 —p"

Я11

a

—1 1

Я12

у

or

' = Я11 — "^12 У = Я12 — Я11

We assume that the reduced-form parameters л11, я12, m2, m12 and m2 have been estimated. The identification problem is one of recovering a, ", ", oj2 and o12 and o| from the reduced-form parameters.

From the second equation, it is clear that у is identified. We now exam­ine the relation between £ and fi given by £ = BfiB0 where B = ^ — . Thus, we have

of = m1 — 2Pm12 + P2m2,

012 = - m2 + (1 + P)mi2 — Pm^ o-2 = m2 — 2m12 C m.

Knowledge of mi, m12, and m2 is enough to recover o|. Hence, o| is iden­tified. Note, however, that o2 and o12 depend on ". Also, a is dependent on ". Hence, given any " = "*, we can solve for a, oj2 and o12. Thus, in principle, we have an infinity of solutions as the choice of " varies. Identifi­cation could have been studied using rank and order conditions. However, in a simple framework as this, it is easier to check identification directly. Identification can be reached by imposing an extra restriction f (", a, oj2, o12) = 0, which is independent of the three equations we have for of, o12 and a. For example, " = 0 gives a recursive structure. We now study the particular case where f (", a, o2, o12) = o12 = 0.

b. Identification with oj2 = 0: When o12 = 0, one can solve immediately for P from the o12 equation:

P = m12 — mf

m22 — m12

Therefore, P can be recovered from m^ m12, and m2. Given ", all the other parameters (of, a) can be recovered as discussed above.

c. OLS estimation of ft when aj2 = 0: The OLS estimator of " is

T T

л E (yt1— y 1 )(yt2— y2) E (ut1 — u1 )(yt1— y 1)

P ols = V = P C---------------- V

T

E(ut1 — u1)(ut2 — ЇЇ2)

t=1_____________________

T

E(yt2 — y2)2

t=1

The second term is non-zero in probability limit as yti and uti are correlated from the first structural equation. Hence "ols is not consistent.

d. From the second structural equation, we have yt2 — yt1 = у + ut2, which means that (yt2 — y2) — (yt1 — y 1) = ut2 — u2, or zt = ut2 — u2. When

an = 0, this zt is clearly uncorrelated with ut1 and by definition correlated withyt2. Therefore, zt = (yt2 —y2) — (yt1 —y1) maybe taken as instruments, and thus

T T

E zt(yt1 — yi) E(yt1 — yi)[(yt2 — y2) — (yt1 — yi)]

" t=i t=i

"IV = —-------------------------- = —-----------------------------------------------------------------

Ё zt(yt2 — y2) Ё(yt2 — y2)[(yt2 — y2) — (yt1 — yi)]

t=i t=i

obtained in part (d). The OLS estimators of the reduced-form parameters are consistent. Therefore, "ILS which is a continuous tranform of those estimators is also consistent. It is however, useful to show this consistency directly since it brings out the role of the identifying restriction.

From the structural equations, we have

" i — p"

yt1 — yi

ut1 — ui

—i i

yt2 — y2

ut2 — Й2

Using the above relation and with some algebra, it can be shown that for

" Ф i:

T T

E(Ul - Ul)(Ut2 - Ui) + " E(^2 - П2)2

t=1 t=1

P ILS = T----------------------------------------- T since,

(utl - ui)(ut2 - u2) + (ut2 - u2)2

t=1 t=1

TT plimT £(ut! - TN1)(ut2 - 1N2) = 012, and plimT £(ut2 - u)2 = of.

t=1 t=1

Therefore, plim "ILS = (о12 + bof) / (o12 C of) . The restriction o12 = 0 implies plim pils = " which proves consistency. It is clear that"ILS can be interpreted as a method-of-moments estimator.

11.24 Errors in Measurement and the Wald (1940) Estimator. This is based on Farebrother (1987).

a. The simple IV estimator of " with instrument z is given by "IV =

n n n

E ziyi zixi. But E ziyi = sum of the yi’s from the second sam-

i=1 i=1 i=1

ple minus the sum of the yi’s from the first sample. If n is even, then

nn

Eziyi = |(y2 - y 1). Similarly, £ziXi = |(x2 - x 1), so that "iv =

i=1 i=1

(y2 - y1)/(x2 - X0 = "W.

b. Let p2 = of/ (^u C of) and x2 = of/ (o2 + of) then Wi = p2Xi* - x2u

has mean E(wi) = 0 since E (xi*) = E(ui) = 0. Also, var(wD = (P2)2°* + (£2)2ou2 = o*ou= (o* + ou).

Since wi is a linear combination of Normal random variables, it is also Normal.

E(xiwi) = p2E (xix*) - x2E(xiui) = p2of - x2o2 = 0.

c. Now £2xi C wi = X2 (xi* C ui) C p2xi* - £2ui = (x2 C p2)xi* = xi* since

X2 C p2 = 1.

Using this result and the fact that yi = "xi* C £i, we get

nn

PW = ^2 *yi/l>i

i=1 i=1

(n n n n

zixi + ^i/ ^ zixi

i=i i=i i=i i=i

so that E("W/x1, ..,xn) = "x2. This follows because wi and ei are independent of xi and therefore independent of zi which is a function of xi. Similarly, "ols = p xiyi p xi2 = "x2 + " p wixi p xi2 +

i=i i=i i=i i=i

nn

Exi£i xi2 so that E("ols/x1, ..,xn) = "x2 since wi and ei are inde-

i=i i=i

pendent of xi. Therefore, the bias of "ols = bias of "W = ("x2 — ") = _PCT,2 / (CT* + CT,2) for all choices of zi which are a function of xi.

11.25 Comparison oft-ratios. This is based onFarebrother(1991). LetZ1 = [y2,X], then by the FWL-Theorem, OLS on the first equation is equivalent to that on P Xyi = рхУ2а+р xui. This yields a ols = (у2РхУ2) 1 y^j5 Xyi and the residual sum of squares are equivalent

yiPzyi = yiPxyi — yiPxy2 (y2pxy^ i y2pxyi so that var(aols) = s^ (y213Xy2) i where s^ = yiPzyi/(T — K). The t-ratio for

a = 0 is

= (T — к)1/2(у2РхУі!) [(yiРхУі)(у2РхУ2) — (yipxy2)r|i/2 .

This expression is unchanged if the roles of yi and y2 are reversed so that the t-ratio for Hb у = 0 in the second equation is the same as that for Ho; a = 0 in the first equation.

Foryi andy2 jointly Normal with correlation coefficient p, Farebrother(1991) shows that the above two tests correspond to a test for p = 0 in the bivariate Normal model so that it makes sense that the two statistics are identical.

11.28 This gives the backup runs for Crime Data for 1987 for Tables 11.2 to 11.6

. ivreg lcrmrte (lprbarr lpolpc= ltaxpc lmix) lprbconv lprbpris lavgsen ldensity lwcon lwtuc lwtrd lwfir lwser lwmfg lwfed lwsta lwloc lpctymle lpctmin west central urban if

year==87

Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression

Number of obs= 90

F(20,69) = 17.35

Prob > F =0.0000 R-squared =0.8446 Adj R-squared =0.7996 Root MSE =.24568

lcrmrte

Coef.

Std. Err.

t

P>|t|

[95% Conf. Interval]

lprbarr

-.4393081

.2267579

-1.94

0.057

-.8916777

.0130615

lpolpc

.5136133

.1976888

2.60

0.011

.1192349

.9079918

lprbconv

-.2713278

.0847024

-3.20

0.002

-.4403044

-.1023512

lprbpris

-.0278416

.1283276

-0.22

0.829

-.2838482

.2281651

lavgsen

-.280122

.1387228

-2.02

0.047

-.5568663

-.0033776

ldensity

.3273521

.0893292

3.66

0.000

.1491452

.505559

lwcon

.3456183

.2419206

1.43

0.158

-.137

.8282366

lwtuc

.1773533

.1718849

1.03

0.306

-.1655477

.5202542

lwtrd

.212578

.3239984

0.66

0.514

-.433781

.8589371

lwfir

-.3540903

.2612516

-1.36

0.180

-.8752731

.1670925

lwser

-.2911556

.1122454

-2.59

0.012

-.5150789

-.0672322

lwmfg

.0642196

.1644108

0.39

0.697

-.263771

.3922102

lwfed

.2974661

.3425026

0.87

0.388

-.3858079

.9807402

lwsta

.0037846

.3102383

0.01

0.990

-.615124

.6226931

lwloc

-.4336541

.5166733

-0.84

0.404

-1.464389

.597081

lpctymle

.0095115

.1869867

0.05

0.960

-.3635166

.3825397

lpctmin

.2285766

.0543079

4.21

0.000

.1202354

.3369179

west

-.0952899

.1301449

-0.73

0.467

-.3549219

.1643422

central

-.1792662

.0762815

-2.35

0.022

-.3314437

-.0270888

urban

-.1139416

.143354

-0.79

0.429

-.3999251

.1720419

_cons

-1.159015

3.898202

-0.30

0.767

-8.935716

6.617686

Instrumented: lprbarr lpolpc

Instruments: lprbconv lprbpris lavgsen ldensity lwcon lwtuc lwtrd lwfir lwser lwmfg

lwfed lwsta lwloc lpctymle lpctmin west central urban ltaxpc lmix

. estimates store b2sls

. reg lcrmrte lprbarr lprbconv lprbpris lavgsen lpolpc ldensity lwcon lwtuc lwtrd lwfir lwser lwmfg lwfed lwsta lwloc lpctymle lpctmin west central urban if year==87

Source

SS

df

MS

Number of obs

=

90

F(20,69)

=

19.71

Model

22.8072483

20

1.14036241

Prob > F

=

0.0000

Residual

3.99245334

69

.057861643

R-squared

=

0.8510

Adj R-squared

=

0.8078

Total

26.7997016

89

.301120243

Root MSE

=

.24054

lcrmrte

Coef.

Std. Err.

t

P>|t|

[95% Conf. Interval]

lprbarr

-.4522907

.0816261

-5.54

0.000

-.6151303

-.2894511

lprbconv

-.3003044

.0600259

-5.00

0.000

-.4200527

-.180556

lprbpris

-.0340435

.1251096

-0.27

0.786

-.2836303

.2155433

lavgsen

-.2134467

.1167513

-1.83

0.072

-.4463592

.0194659

lpolpc

.3610463

.0909534

3.97

0.000

.1795993

.5424934

ldensity

.3149706

.0698265

4.51

0.000

.1756705

.4542707

lwcon

.2727634

.2198714

1.24

0.219

-.165868

.7113949

lwtuc

.1603777

.1666014

0.96

0.339

-.171983

.4927385

lwtrd

.1325719

.3005086

0.44

0.660

-.4669263

.7320702

lwfir

-.3205858

.251185

-1.28

0.206

-.8216861

.1805146

lwser

-.2694193

.1039842

-2.59

0.012

-.4768622

-.0619765

lwmfg

.1029571

.1524804

0.68

0.502

-.2012331

.4071472

lwfed

.3856593

.3215442

1.20

0.234

-.2558039

1.027123

lwsta

-.078239

.2701264

-0.29

0.773

-.6171264

.4606485

lwloc

-.1774064

.4251793

-0.42

0.678

-1.025616

.670803

lpctymle

.0326912

.1580377

0.21

0.837

-.2825855

.3479678

lpctmin

.2245975

.0519005

4.33

0.000

.1210589

.3281361

west

-.087998

.1243235

-0.71

0.481

-.3360167

.1600207

central

-.1771378

.0739535

-2.40

0.019

-.3246709

-.0296046

urban

-.0896129

.1375084

-0.65

0.517

-.3639347

.184709

_cons

-3.395919

3.020674

-1.12

0.265

-9.421998

2.630159

. estimates store bols. hausman b2sls bols

Coefficients

(b)

b2sls

(B)

bols

(b-B)

Difference

sqrt(diag(V_b-V_

S. E.

lprbarr

-.4393081

-.4522907

.0129826

.2115569

lpolpc

.5136133

.3610463

.152567

.1755231

lprbconv

-.2713278

-.3003044

.0289765

.0597611

lprbpris

-.0278416

-.0340435

.0062019

.0285582

lavgsen

-.280122

-.2134467

-.0666753

.0749208

ldensity

.3273521

.3149706

.0123815

.0557132

lwcon

.3456183

.2727634

.0728548

.1009065

lwtuc

.1773533

.1603777

.0169755

.0422893

lwtrd

.212578

.1325719

.0800061

.1211178

lwfir

-.3540903

-.3205858

-.0335045

.0718228

lwser

-.2911556

-.2694193

-.0217362

.0422646

lwmfg

.0642196

.1029571

-.0387375

.0614869

lwfed

.2974661

.3856593

-.0881932

.1179718

b = consistent under Ho and Ha; obtained from ivreg B = inconsistent under Ha, efficient under Ho; obtained from regress

Test: Ho: difference in coefficients not systematic chi2(20) = (b-B)'[(V_b-V_B)~ (-1)](b-B)

= 0.87

Prob > chi2 = 1.0000

. ivreg Icrmrte (Iprbarr lpolpc= Itaxpc Imix) Iprbconv Iprbpris lavgsen Idensity Iwcon Iwtuc Iwtrd Iwfir Iwser Iwmfg Iwfed Iwsta IwIoc IpctymIe Ipctmin west centraI urban if year==87, first

First-stage regressions

90

3.11

0.0002

0.4742

0.3218

.33174

Iprbarr

Coef.

Std. Err.

t

P>|t|

[95% Conf. IntervaI]

Iprbconv

-.1946392

.0877581

-2.22

0.030

-.3697119

-.0195665

Iprbpris

-.0240173

.1732583

-0.14

0.890

-.3696581

.3216236

Iavgsen

.1565061

.1527134

1.02

0.309

-.1481488

.4611611

Idensity

-.2211654

.0941026

-2.35

0.022

-.408895

-.0334357

Iwcon

-.2024569

.3020226

-0.67

0.505

-.8049755

.4000616

Iwtuc

-.0461931

.230479

-0.20

0.842

-.5059861

.4135999

Iwtrd

.0494793

.4105612

0.12

0.904

-.769568

.8685266

Iwfir

.050559

.3507405

0.14

0.886

-.6491492

.7502671

Iwser

.0551851

.1500094

0.37

0.714

-.2440754

.3544456

Iwmfg

.0550689

.2138375

0.26

0.798

-.3715252

.481663

Iwfed

.2622408

.4454479

0.59

0.558

-.6264035

1.150885

Iwsta

-.4843599

.3749414

-1.29

0.201

-1.232347

.2636277

IwIoc

.7739819

.5511607

1.40

0.165

-.3255536

1.873517

IpctymIe

-.3373594

.2203286

-1.53

0.130

-.776903

.1021842

Ipctmin

-.0096724

.0729716

-0.13

0.895

-.1552467

.1359019

west

.0701236

.1756211

0.40

0.691

-.280231

.4204782

centraI

.0112086

.1034557

0.11

0.914

-.1951798

.217597

lcrmrte

Coef.

Std. Err.

t

P>|t|

[95% Conf. Interval]

lprbarr

-.4393081

.2267579

-1.94

0.057

-.8916777

.0130615

lpolpc

.5136133

.1976888

2.60

0.011

.1192349

.9079918

lprbconv

-.2713278

.0847024

-3.20

0.002

-.4403044

-.1023512

lprbpris

-.0278416

.1283276

-0.22

0.829

-.2838482

.2281651

lavgsen

-.280122

.1387228

-2.02

0.047

-.5568663

-.0033776

ldensity

.3273521

.0893292

3.66

0.000

.1491452

.505559

lwcon

.3456183

.2419206

1.43

0.158

-.137

.8282366

if year==87

Source

1 SS

df

MS

Number of obs

= 90

= 4.42

F(20,69)

Model

6.99830344

20

.349915172 Prob > F

= 0.0000

Residual

5.46683312

69

.079229465 R-squared

= 0.5614

= 0.4343

Total

1 12.4651366

89

.140057714 Root MSE

= .28148

lpolpc

Coef.

Std. Err.

t

P>|t|

[95% Conf. Interval]

lmix

.2177256

.0733414

2.97

0.004

.0714135

.3640378

ltaxpc

.5601989

.1489398

3.76

0.000

.2630721

.8573258

lprbconv

.0037744

.0744622

0.05

0.960

-.1447736

.1523223

lprbpris

-.0487064

.1470085

-0.33

0.741

-.3419802

.2445675

lavgsen

.3958972

.1295763

3.06

0.003

.1373996

.6543948

ldensity

.0201292

.0798454

0.25

0.802

-.1391581

.1794165

lwcon

-.5368469

.2562641

-2.09

0.040

-1.04808

-.025614

lwtuc

-.0216638

.1955598

-0.11

0.912

-.411795

.3684674

lwtrd

-.4207274

.3483584

-1.21

0.231

-1.115683

.2742286

lwfir

.0001257

.2976009

0.00

1.000

-.5935718

.5938232

lwser

.0973089

.1272819

0.76

0.447

-.1566116

.3512293

lwmfg

.1710295

.1814396

0.94

0.349

-.1909327

.5329916

lwfed

.8555422

.3779595

2.26

0.027

.1015338

1.609551

lwsta

-.1118764

.3181352

-0.35

0.726

-.7465387

.5227859

lwloc

1.375102

.4676561

2.94

0.004

.4421535

2.30805

lpctymle

.4186939

.1869473

2.24

0.028

.0457442

.7916436

lpctmin

-.0517966

.0619159

-0.84

0.406

-.1753154

.0717222

west

.1458865

.1490133

0.98

0.331

-.151387

.4431599

central

.0477227

.0877814

0.54

0.588

-.1273964

.2228419

urban

-.1192027

.1719407

-0.69

0.490

-.4622151

.2238097

_cons

-16.33148

3.221824

-5.07

0.000

-22.75884

-9.904113

The test that the additional instruments are jointly significant in the first stage regression for Ipolpc is performed as follows:

. test lmix=ltaxpc=0

(1) lmix - ltaxpc = 0

(2) lmix = 0

F(2,69) = 10.56 Prob > F = 0.0001

. ivregress 2sls Icrmrte (Iprbarr lpolpc= Itaxpc Imix) Iprbconv Iprbpris lavgsen Idensity Iwcon Iwtuc Iwtrd Iwfir Iwser Iwmfg Iwfed Iwsta Iwloc Ipctymle Ipctmin west central urban if year==87

InstrumentaI variabIes (2SLS) regression

Number of obs

= 90

WaId chi2(20)

= 452.49

Prob > chi2

= 0.0000

R-squared

= 0.8446

Root MSE

= .21511

Icrmrte

Coef.

Std. Err.

z

P>|z|

[95% Conf. IntervaI]

Iprbarr

-.4393081

.1985481

-2.21

0.027

-.8284552

-.050161

IpoIpc

.5136133

.1730954

2.97

0.003

.1743526

.852874

Iprbconv

-.2713278

.074165

-3.66

0.000

-.4166885

-.1259672

Iprbpris

-.0278416

.112363

-0.25

0.804

-.2480691

.1923859

Iavgsen

-.280122

.121465

-2.31

0.021

-.5181889

-.042055

Idensity

.3273521

.0782162

4.19

0.000

.1740512

.4806531

Iwcon

.3456183

.2118244

1.63

0.103

-.06955

.7607865

Iwtuc

.1773533

.1505016

1.18

0.239

-.1176244

.4723309

Iwtrd

.212578

.2836914

0.75

0.454

-.3434468

.7686029

Iwfir

-.3540903

.2287506

-1.55

0.122

-.8024333

.0942527

Iwser

-.2911556

.0982815

-2.96

0.003

-.4837837

-.0985274

Iwmfg

.0642196

.1439573

0.45

0.656

-.2179316

.3463707

Iwfed

.2974661

.2998936

0.99

0.321

-.2903145

.8852468

Iwsta

.0037846

.2716432

0.01

0.989

-.5286262

.5361954

Iwtuc

.1773533

.1718849

1.03

0.306

-.1655477

.5202542

Iwtrd

.212578

.3239984

0.66

0.514

-.433781

.8589371

Iwfir

-.3540903

.2612516

-1.36

0.180

-.8752731

.1670925

Iwser

-.2911556

.1122454

-2.59

0.012

-.5150789

-.0672322

Iwmfg

.0642196

.1644108

0.39

0.697

-.263771

.3922102

Iwfed

.2974661

.3425026

0.87

0.388

-.3858079

.9807402

Iwsta

.0037846

.3102383

0.01

0.990

-.615124

.6226931

IwIoc

-.4336541

.5166733

-0.84

0.404

-1.464389

.597081

IpctymIe

.0095115

.1869867

0.05

0.960

-.3635166

.3825397

Ipctmin

.2285766

.0543079

4.21

0.000

.1202354

.3369179

west

-.0952899

.1301449

-0.73

0.467

-.3549219

.1643422

centraI

-.1792662

.0762815

-2.35

0.022

-.3314437

-.0270888

urban

-.1139416

.143354

-0.79

0.429

-.3999251

.1720419

_cons

-1.159015

3.898202

-0.30

0.767

-8.935716

6.617686

Instrumented: Iprbarr Ipolpc

Instruments: Iprbconv Iprbpris lavgsen Idensity Iwcon Iwtuc Iwtrd Iwfir Iwser Iwmfg

Iwfed Iwsta Iwloc Ipctymle Ipctmin west central urban Itaxpc Imix

. reg Iprbarr Imix Itaxpc Iprbconv Iprbpris lavgsen Idensity Iwcon Iwtuc Iwtrd Iwfir Iwser Iwmfg Iwfed Iwsta Iwloc Ipctymle Ipctmin west central urban if year==87

Source

1 SS

df

MS

Number of obs F(20, 69)

= 90 = 3.11

Model

6.84874028

20

.342437014

Prob > F

= 0.0002

Residual

7.59345096

69

.110050014

R-squared Adj R-squared

= 0.4742 = 0.3218

Total

1 14.4421912

89

.162271812

Root MSE

= .33174

lprbarr

Coef.

Std. Err.

t

P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval]

lmix

.2682143

.0864373

3.10

0.003 .0957766

.4406519

ltaxpc

-.1938134

.1755345

-1.10

0.273 -.5439952

.1563684

lprbconv

-.1946392

.0877581

-2.22

0.030 -.3697119

-.0195665

lprbpris

-.0240173

.1732583

-0.14

0.890 -.3696581

.3216236

lavgsen

.1565061

.1527134

1.02

0.309 -.1481488

.4611611

ldensity

-.2211654

.0941026

-2.35

0.022 -.408895

-.0334357

lwcon

-.2024569

.3020226

-0.67

0.505 -.8049755

.4000616

lwtuc

-.0461931

.230479

-0.20

0.842 -.5059861

.4135999

lwtrd

.0494793

.4105612

0.12

0.904 -.769568

.8685266

lwfir

.050559

.3507405

0.14

0.886 -.6491492

.7502671

lwser

.0551851

.1500094

0.37

0.714 -.2440754

.3544456

lwmfg

.0550689

.2138375

0.26

0.798 -.3715252

.481663

lwfed

.2622408

.4454479

0.59

0.558 -.6264035

1.150885

lwsta

-.4843599

.3749414

-1.29

0.201 -1.232347

.2636277

lwloc

.7739819

.5511607

1.40

0.165 -.3255536

1.873517

lpctymle

-.3373594

.2203286

-1.53

0.130 -.776903

.1021842

lpctmin

-.0096724

.0729716

-0.13

0.895 -.1552467

.1359019

west

.0701236

.1756211

0.40

0.691 -.280231

.4204782

central

.0112086

.1034557

0.11

0.914 -.1951798

.217597

urban

-.0150372

.2026425

-0.07

0.941 -.4192979

.3892234

_cons

-4.319234

3.797113

-1.14

0.259 -11.89427

3.255799

Then we can test that the additional instruments are jointly significant in the first stage regression for Iprbarr as follows:

. test lmix=ltaxpc=0

(1) lmix - ltaxpc = 0

(2) lmix = 0

F(2, 69) = 5.78
Prob > F = 0.0048

For lpolpc, the first stage regression is given by

. reg lpolpc lmix ltaxpc lprbconv lprbpris lavgsen ldensity lwcon lwtuc lwtrd lwfir lwser lwmfg lwfed lwsta lwloc lpctymle lpctmin west central urban

lwloc

-.4336541

.4523966

-0.96

0.338

-1.320335

.453027

lpctymle

.0095115

.1637246

0.06

0.954

-.3113827

.3304058

lpctmin

.2285766

.0475517

4.81

0.000

.135377

.3217763

west

-.0952899

.1139543

-0.84

0.403

-.3186361

.1280564

central

-.1792662

.0667917

-2.68

0.007

-.3101756

-.0483569

urban -.1139416 .1255201 -0.91 0.364 -.3599564 .1320732

.cons -1.159015 3.413247 -0.34 0.734 -7.848855 5.530825

Instrumented: Iprbarr Ipolpc

Instruments: lprbconv lprbpris lavgsen ldensity lwcon lwtuc lwtrd lwfir lwser lwmfg lwfed

lwsta lwloc lpctymle lpctmin west central urban ltaxpc lmix

. estat firststage

Shea's partial R-squared

Shea's

Shea's

Variable

Partial R-sq.

Adj. Partial R-sq.

lprbarr

0.1352

-0.0996

lpolpc

0.2208

0.0093

Minimum eigenvalue statistic = 5.31166

Critical Values # of endogenous regressors: 2

Ho: Instruments are weak # of excluded instruments: 2

5%

10%

20%

30%

2SLS relative bias

(not available)

10%

15%

20%

25%

2SLS Size of nominal 5% Wald test

7.03

4.58

3.95

3.63

LIML Size of nominal 5% Wald test

7.03

4.58

3.95

3.63

One can run the same IV regressions for other years, but this is not done here to save space.

11.30 Growth and Inequality Reconsidered

a. The 3SLS results are replicated using Stata below:

reg3 (Growth: dly = yrt gov m2y inf swo dtot f_pcy d80 d90) (Inequality: gih = yrt m2y civ mlg mlgldc), exog(commod f. civ f_dem Ldtot f. flit f. gov Lint f_m2y f_swo

f. yrt pop urb lex lfr marea oil legor_fr legor_ge legor_mx legor_ sc legor_uk) endog (yrt gov m2y inf swo civ mlg mlgldc)

Three-stage least-squares regression

Equation

Obs

Parms

RMSE

“R-sq”

chi2

P

Growth

119

9

2.34138

0.3905

65.55

0.0000

Inequality

119

5

7.032975

0.4368

94.28

0.0000

Coef.

Std. Err.

z

P>|z|

[95% Conf. Interval]

Growth

yrt

-.0280625

.1827206

-0.15

0.878

-.3861882

.3300632

gov

-.0533221

.0447711

-1.19

0.234

-.1410718

.0344276

m2y

.0085368

.0199759

0.43

0.669

-.0306152

.0476889

inf

-.0008174

.0025729

-0.32

0.751

-.0058602

.0042254

swo

4.162776

.9499015

4.38

0.000

2.301003

6.024548

dtot

26.03736

23.05123

1.13

0.259

-19.14221

71.21694

f-pcy

-1.38017

.5488437

-2.51

0.012

-2.455884

-.3044564

d80

-1.560392

.545112

-2.86

0.004

-2.628792

-.4919922

d90

-3.413661

.6539689

-5.22

0.000

-4.695417

-2.131906

_cons

13.00837

3.968276

3.28

0.001

5.230693

20.78605

Inequality

yrt

-1.244464

.4153602

-3.00

0.003

-2.058555

-.4303731

m2y

-.120124

.0581515

-2.07

0.039

-.2340989

-.0061492

civ

.2531189

.7277433

0.35

0.728

-1.173232

1.67947

mlg

.292672

.0873336

3.35

0.001

.1215012

.4638428

mlgldc

-.0547843

.0576727

-0.95

0.342

-.1678207

.0582522

_cons

33.13231

5.517136

6.01

0.000

22.31893

43.9457

Endogenous variables: dly gih yrt gov m2y inf swo civ mlg mlgldc Exogenous variables: dtot f_pcy d80 d90 commod Lciv Ldem Ldtot f_flit Lgov Linf Lm2y Lswo Lyrt pop urb lex lfr marea oil legor_fr legor_ge legor_mx legor_sc legor_uk

b. The 3sls results of the respecified equations are replicated using Stata below:

. reg3 (Growth: dly = gih yrt gov m2y inf swo dtot f_pcy d80 d90) (Inequality: gih = dly yrt m2y civ mlg mlgldc), exog(f_civ Ldem Ldtot Lflit Lgov Linf f_m2y Lswo Lyrt pop urb lex lfr marea commod oil legor_fr legor_ge legor_mx legor_sc legon. uk) endog(yrt gov m2y inf swo civ mlg mlgldc)

Three-stage least-squares regression

Equation

Obs

Parms

RMSE

“R-sq”

chi2

P

Growth

119

10

2.366525

0.3773

65.26

0.0000

Inequality

119

6

6.969627

0.4469

96.06

0.0000

Coef.

Std. Err.

z

P>|z|

[95% Conf. Interval]

-----------------------

Growth

gih

-.0181063

.0452471

-0.40

0.689

-.106789

.0705763

yrt

-.0642514

.1971126

-0.33

0.744

-.4505851

.3220822

gov

-.0559828

.0457033

-1.22

0.221

-.1455597

.0335941

m2y

.0084914

.0201616

0.42

0.674

-.0310246

.0480074

inf

.0002947

.0031579

0.09

0.926

-.0058948

.0064841

swo

4.148469

.9771934

4.25

0.000

2.233205

6.063733

dtot

28.56603

23.60078

1.21

0.226

-17.69064

74.8227

f-pcy

-1.35157

.5565555

-2.43

0.015

-2.442399

-.2607418

d80

-1.581281

.5498957

-2.88

0.004

-2.659057

-.503505

d90

-3.392124

.6624323

-5.12

0.000

-4.690467

-2.09378

cons

13.67011

4.382862

3.12

0.002

5.079854

22.26036

Inequality

dly

.2642484

.3586634

0.74

0.461

-.438719

.9672158

yrt

-1.221263

.4122647

-2.96

0.003

-2.029286

-.4132386

m2y

-.115859

.0577899

-2.00

0.045

-.2291251

-.0025929

civ

.1510064

.7449721

0.20

0.839

-1.309112

1.611125

mlg

.2951145

.0870164

3.39

0.001

.1245654

.4656635

mlgldc

-.0451182

.0581734

-0.78

0.438

-.159136

.0688996

_cons

32.06252

5.611046

5.71

0.000

21.06507

43.05997

Endogenous variables: dly gih yrt gov m2y inf swo civ mlg mlgldc Exogenous variables: dtot f_pcy d80 d90 f_civ Ldem Ldtot Lflit Lgov Linf Lm2y Lswo Lyrt pop urb lex lfr marea commod oil legorJr legor_ge legor_mx legor_sc legor_uk

11.31 Married Women Labor Supply

b. The following Stata output replicates Equation 2 of Table IV of Mroz (1987, p. 770) which runs 2SLS using the following instrumental variables:

. local B unem city motheduc fatheduc. local E exper expersq. local control age educ

. ivregress 2sls hours (lwage= ‘B’ ‘E’) nwifeinc kidslt6 kidsge6 ‘control’, vce(robust)

Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression Number of obs = 428

Wald chi2(6) = 18.67

Prob > chi2 = 0.0048

R-squared = .

Root MSE = 1141.3

hours

Coef.

Robust Std. Err.

z

P>|z|

[95% Conf. Interval]

lwage

1261.574

460.7772

2.74

0.006

358.4673

2164.681

nwifeinc

-8.341979

4.586405

-1.82

0.069

-17.33117

.6472101

kidslt6

-234.7069

182.201

-1.29

0.198

-591.8143

122.4005

kidsge6

-59.78876

49.04792

-1.22

0.223

-155.9209

36.34341

age

-10.23035

9.264046

-1.10

0.269

-28.38755

7.926846

educ

-147.895

52.71884

-2.81

0.005

-251.222

-44.56794

_cons

2374.632

531.9775

4.46

0.000

1331.976

3417.289

Instrumented: Iwage

Instruments: nwifeinc kidslt6 kidsge6 age educ unem city motheduc fatheduc exper expersq

estat overid

Test of overidentifying restrictions: Score chi2(5) = 5.9522 (p = 0.3109)

estat firststage, forcenonrobust all
First-stage regression summary statistics

Adjusted

Partial

Robust

Variable

R-sq.

R-sq.

R-sq.

F(6,416)

Prob > F

lwage

0.1719

0.1500

0.0468

2.58071

0.0182

Shea’s partial R-squared

Shea’s

Shea’s

Variable

Partial R-sq. Adj. Partial R-sq.

lwage

0.0468

0.0240

Minimum eigenvalue statistic = 3.40543

Critical Values # of endogenous regressors: 1

Ho: Instruments are weak # of excluded instruments: 6

5%

10%

20%

30%

2SLS relative bias

19.28

11.12

6.76

5.15

10%

15%

20%

25%

2SLS Size of nominal 5% Wald test

29.18

16.23

11.72

9.38

LIML Size of nominal 5% Wald test

4.45

3.34

2.87

2.61

Similarly, the following Stata output replicates Equation 3 of Table IV of Mroz(1987, p. 770) which runs 2SLS using the following instrumental variables: . local F2 age2 educ2 age_educ

. ivregress 2sls hours (lwage= ‘B’ ‘E’ ‘F2’) nwifeinc kidslt6 kidsge6 ‘control’, vce(robust)

Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression

Number of obs

= 428

Wald chi2(6)

= 24.56

Prob > chi2

= 0.0004

R-squared

=.

Root MSE

= 942.03

hours

Coef.

Robust Std. Err.

z

P>|z|

[95% Conf. Interval]

lwage

831.2505

312.1889

2.66

0.008

219.3715

1443.129

nwifeinc

-6.963789

3.814549

-1.83

0.068

-14.44017

.5125885

kidslt6

-270.9764

154.5197

-1.75

0.079

-573.8294

31.87667

kidsge6

-78.37192

39.257

-2.00

0.046

-155.3142

-1.429619

age

-9.38908

7.589533

-1.24

0.216

-24.26429

5.486132

educ

-102.9946

36.35213

-2.83

0.005

-174.2435

-31.74576

_cons

2287.175

432.9381

5.28

0.000

1438.632

3135.718

Instrumented: lwage

Instruments: nwifeinc kidslt6 kidsge6 age educ unem city motheduc fatheduc exper expersq age2 educ2 age_educ

. estat overid

Test of overidentifying restrictions: Score chi2(8) = 19.8895 (p = 0.0108)

. estat firststage, forcenonrobust all First-stage regression summary statistics

Adjusted

Partial

Robust

Variable

R-sq.

R-sq.

R-sq.

F(6,416)

Prob > F

lwage

0.1846

0.1570

0.0614

2.3555

0.0133

Shea’s partial R-squared

Shea’s

Shea’s

Variable

Partial R-sq. Adj. PartialR-sq.

lwage

0.0614

0.0320

Minimum eigenvalue statistic = 3.0035

Critical Values # of endogenous regressors: 1

Ho: Instruments are weak # of excluded instruments: 9

5%

10%

20%

30%

2SLS relative bias

20.53

11.46

6.65

4.92

10%

15%

20%

25%

2SLS Size of nominal 5% Wald test

36.19

19.71

14.01

11.07

LIML Size of nominal 5% Wald test

3.81

2.93

2.54

2.32

Similarly, one can generate the rest of the regressions in Table IV and their related diagnostics.

References

Baltagi, B. H. (1989), “A Hausman Specification Test in a Simultaneous Equations Model,”Econometric Theory, Solution 88.3.5, 5: 453-467.

Farebrother, R. W. (1987), “The Exact Bias of Wald’s Estimation,” Econometric Theory, Solution 85.3.1, 3: 162.

Farebrother, R. W. (1991), “Comparison of t-Ratios,” Econometric Theory, Solution 90.1.4,7: 145-146.

Hausman, J. A. (1983), “Specification and Estimation of Simultaneous Equation Models,” Chapter 7 in Griliches, Z. and Intriligator, M. D. (eds.) Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. I (North Holland: Amsterdam).

Laffer, A. B., (1970), “Trade Credit and the Money Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 78: 239-267.

Mroz, T. A. (1987), “The Sensitivity of an Empirical Model of Married Women’s Hours of Work to Economic and Statistical Assumptions,” Econometrica, 55: 765-799.

Singh, N. and A N. Bhat (1988), “Identification and Estimation of a Simple Two - Equation Model,” Econometric Theory, Solution 87.3.3, 4: 542-545.

Theil, H. (1971), Principles of Econometrics (Wiley: New York).

Wald, A. (1940), “Fitting of Straight Lines if Both Variables are Subject to Error,” Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 11: 284-300.

CHAPTER 12

Добавить комментарий

Springer Texts in Business and Economics

The General Linear Model: The Basics

7.1 Invariance of the fitted values and residuals to non-singular transformations of the independent variables. The regression model in (7.1) can be written as y = XCC-1" + u where …

Regression Diagnostics and Specification Tests

8.1 Since H = PX is idempotent, it is positive semi-definite with b0H b > 0 for any arbitrary vector b. Specifically, for b0 = (1,0,.., 0/ we get hn …

Generalized Least Squares

9.1 GLS Is More Efficient than OLS. a. Equation (7.5) of Chap. 7 gives "ois = " + (X'X)-1X'u so that E("ois) = " as long as X and u …

Как с нами связаться:

Украина:
г.Александрия
тел./факс +38 05235  77193 Бухгалтерия

+38 050 457 13 30 — Рашид - продажи новинок
e-mail: msd@msd.com.ua
Схема проезда к производственному офису:
Схема проезда к МСД

Партнеры МСД

Контакты для заказов оборудования:

Внимание! На этом сайте большинство материалов - техническая литература в помощь предпринимателю. Так же большинство производственного оборудования сегодня не актуально. Уточнить можно по почте: Эл. почта: msd@msd.com.ua

+38 050 512 1194 Александр
- телефон для консультаций и заказов спец.оборудования, дробилок, уловителей, дражираторов, гереторных насосов и инженерных решений.