Financial Econometrics and Empirical Market Microstructure
Results
When buying or selling a security, investors typically are interested in the following three questions: How likely am I to transact? What price am I likely to receive? How much does this transaction price vary? We therefore estimate the following three observables in the model both with and without HFT: (1) the probability that a submitted order will result in a transaction, (2) the average transaction price of filled orders, and (3) the volatility of the transaction price of filled orders (the standard deviation of the transaction price). We run the simulation 100 times for 10000 time steps both with and without HFT, and we record average values of the relevant observables. The results are shown in Figs. 3 and 4 and in Table 1, which we discuss in more detail below.
The model reproduces several empirical findings that have otherwise been difficult to explain (Hendershott et al. 2011; Hasbrouck and Saar 2013; Brogaard et al. 2013):
1. Transaction prices are more accurate when HFT is present, i. e., they are closer to the equilibrium value.
2. Volatility is reduced when HFT is present.
3. Liquidity is increased when HFT is present.
The equilibrium price, defined as the intersection of the expected aggregate supply and demand curve in the simulation, is just the mean of the uniform distribution of prices, i. e., 100.5. As seen in Table 1, the average transaction price both with and without HFT converges to the equilibrium value within the 2 standard error range that defines a 95 % confidence interval. However, the variance around the equilibrium value is reduced when HFT is added. The reduction in variance is
shown in Table 1 and can be seen in the comparison of the histogram of transaction prices in Fig. 3a,b. As seen in the figure, HFT causes more transactions to occur near the equilibrium price. This result matches previous empirical studies that have shown algorithmic trading in general and HFT specifically increases the accuracy of prices in markets (Brogaard et al. 2013; Hendershott et al. 2011).
Empirical studies have also found that HFT reduces intraday volatility (Has - brouck and Saar 2013). Our simulation reproduces this result as well (see Fig. 4b). Because the equilibrium price is constant in the model, any variance in transaction price can be interpreted as excess volatility. Because HFT reduces the variance of execution prices, it also reduces the volatility of the market.
The final metric we consider is liquidity. An asset is liquid if “it is more certainly realizable at short notice without loss” (Keynes 1930). Liquidity can be defined quantitatively in a number of ways. However, our model accounts for the requirement of short notice, as orders are canceled if they do not result in a transaction, and when they do transact, the price must satisfy the reservation price initially generated. As a result, our measure of liquidity is the number of transactions that take place per simulation, or the probability that an order transacts. As shown
in Table 1 and Fig. 4c,d, orders are more likely to be filled when HFT activity is present in our model. Again, this result matches empirical findings (Hasbrouck and Saar 2013).
Acknowledgements This chapter is a modified version of Benjamin Myers MPhys thesis originally entitled “Agent Based Simulations of High-Frequency Trading in Financial Markets.” This work was supported by the European Commission FP7 FET-Open Project FOC-II (no. 255987).