A COMPANION TO Theoretical Econometrics

Appendix B Existence of Joint Posterior Distribution

image551 Подпись: (22.B1)

Let ю denote the number of missing wage observations, and let Q = [Aq, BQ]“ £ ^++ be the domain of unobserved wages, where 0 < AQ < BQ < Also, let A = [Ад, BA]3NT £ ^3NT be the domain of latent relative utilities, where -^ < Aa < BA < ro. We want to show that:

Here, we have subsumed a and Л into n and ¥, respectively (as we did in Step 5 of Section 3) and defined

g(V, p, E-1) = IE-1 |—exp{-±(V - Yp)'(E-1 ® INT)(V - Yp)}, (22.B2)

where

Подпись:(22.B3)

We have also defined

h(Z, W, n, En1) = |En1 |~exp{-£(Z - W - Wn)'(Ej ® N)(Z - W - Wk)}

■ I(Zijt > 0, Zm(k Ф j) < 0 if dit = j and j £ {1, 2, 3}, {Zjj 1,2,3 < 0 otherwise),

(22.B4)

(0).

Подпись: where

Since the only arguments common to both g and h are those that include func­tions of wages, we can express (22.B1) as

Подпись: gV) Подпись: g(v, P, x-1) < ~. P, E-1 Подпись: (22.B6)

We first observe that for any configuration of unobserved wages in Q,

To see this, note that we can express g(V, p, Eg1) as

g(V, в, Ee) = IE-1 |^exp{-^tr(S(P)E-1) - l(P - P),Y,(E-1 ® INT)Y(p - p)},

(22.B7)

where

S = (Y'(E-1 ® INt)Y)-1Y'(E-1 ® Int)V

S(S) = (V1 - Y1S1, V2 - Y2S2)'(V - Y1S1, V2 - Y2S2) (22.B8)

Hence, g(V, p, Eg) is proportional to a normal-Wishart density (Bernardo and Smith, 1994, p. 140), hence finitely integrable to a value g(V) that, in general, will depend on the configuration of unobserved wages. Since g(V) is finite over the compact set Q, it follows that g(V) is bounded over Q.

Turn next to h(Z, W, n, E,-1). Since (22.B4) has the same form as (22.B2), just as (22.B7) we can write:

h(Z, W, n, Xn1) = |ХЛ1 |^exp{- ^1tr(S(l)En1) - i(n - n)'W'(En1 ® Im№ - I)}

■ I(Zijt > 0, ZiRt(k Ф j) < 0 if du = j and j Є {1, 2, 3}, {Zijt}j=1Z3 < 0 otherwise) (22.B9)

Подпись: h(Z, W) Подпись: h(Z, W, n, En1) < ~ Д ,n,En1 Подпись: (22.B10)

where I and S(I) are defined in a way that is exactly analogous to (22.B8). Hence,

Подпись: J Q,A Подпись: 4j g(V)h(Z, W) Подпись: (22.B11)

for any configuration of unobserved wages in Q and latent utilities in A. It fol­lows that h(Z, W) is bounded over Q x A. Thus, the integral (B1) reduces to

which is finite since each element of the integrand is bounded over the compact domain of integration.

Notes

0 Currently, approaches to numerical integration such as quadrature and series expan­sion are not useful if the dimension of the integration is greater than three or four.

1 Restrictions of this type can be tested easily by estimating versions of the model with different but nested future components.

2 These findings are related to those of Lancaster (1997), who considered Bayesian infer­ence in the stationary job search model. He found that if the future component is treated as a free parameter (rather than being set "optimally" as dictated by the offer wage function, offer arrival rate, unemployment benefit and discount rate) there is little loss of information about the structural parameters of the offer wage functions. (As in our example, however, identification of the discount factor is lost.) The station­ary job search model considered by Lancaster (1997) has the feature that the future component is a constant (i. e. it is not a function of state variables). Our procedure of treating the future component as a polynomial in state variables can be viewed as extending Lancaster's approach to a much more general class of models.

3 As noted earlier, the future component's arguments reflect restrictions implied by the model. For instance, because the productivity and preference shocks are serially inde­pendent, they contain no information useful for forecasting future payoffs and do not appear in the future component's arguments. Also, given total experience in each occupation, the order in which occupations one and two were chosen in the past does not bear on current or future payoffs. Accordingly, only total experience in each occupation enters the future component.

4 To begin the Gibbs algorithm we needed an initial guess for the model's parameters (although the asymptotic behavior of the Gibbs sampler as the number of cycles grows large is independent of starting values). We chose to set the log-wage equation Ps equal to the value from an OLS regression on observed wages. The diagonal elements of £e were set to the variance of observed log-wages, while the off-diagonal elements were set to zero. The school payoff parameters were all initialized at zero. All of the future component's n values were also started at zero, with the exception of the alternative-specific intercepts. The intercepts for alternatives one, two, and three were initialized at -5,000, 10,000, and 20,000, respectively. These values were chosen with an eye towards matching aggregate choice frequencies in each alternative. We initialized the covariance matrix by setting all off-diagonal elements to zero, and each diagonal element to 5 x 108. We used large initial variances because doing so increases the size of the initial Gibbs steps, and seems to improve the rate of con­vergence of the algorithm.

5 Space considerations prevent us from reporting results for individual expectations parameters. Instead, below we will graphically compare the form of the estimated future component to that which was used to generate the data.

6 We also ran OLS accepted log-wage regressions for the 1-EMAX through 5-EMAX data sets. The results are very similar to those in Table 22.4, so we do not report them here. The estimates again show substantial biases for all the wage equation parameters. Thus, the Gibbs sampling algorithm continues to do an impressive job of implement­ing a dynamic selection correction despite the fact that the agents' decision rules are misspecified.

7 The mean state vectors were derived from the choices in data set 5-EMAX, and the coefficients of the polynomial were valued at the posterior means derived from the analysis of data set 5-EMAX.

References

Bernardo, J., and A. F.M. Smith (1994). Bayesian Theory. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Ltd.

Eckstein, Z., and K. Wolpin (1989). The specification and estimation of dynamic stochastic discrete choice models. Journal of Human Resources 24, 562-98.

Gelman, A. (1996). Inference and monitoring convergence. In W. R. Gilks, S. Richardson, and D. J. Spiegelhalter (eds.) Markov Chain Monte Carlo in Practice. pp. 131-43. London: Chapman & Hall.

Geweke, J. (1995). Priors for macroeconomic time series and their application. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

Geweke, J. (1996). Monte Carlo simulation and numerical integration. In H. M. Amman, D. A. Kendrick, and J. Rust (eds.) Handbook of Computational Economics, Volume 1, pp. 731-800.

Geweke, J., and M. Keane (1999a). Bayesian inference for dynamic discrete choice models without the need for dynamic programming. In Mariano, Schuermann, and Weeks (eds.) Simulation Based Inference and Econometrics: Methods and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Also available as Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis working paper #564, January, 1996.)

Geweke, J., and M. Keane (1999b). Computationally intensive methods for integration in econometrics. In J. Heckman and E. Leamer (eds.) Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 5. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Geweke, J., M. Keane, and D. Runkle (1994). Alternative computational approaches to inference in the multinomial probit model. Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 609-32.

Gilks, W. R., S. Richardson, and D. J. Spiegelhalter (1996). Introducing Markov Chain Monte Carlo. In W. R. Gilks, S. Richardson, and D. J. Spiegelhalter (eds.) Markov Chain Monte Carlo in Practice. pp. 1-20. London: Chapman & Hall.

Heckman, J. (1976). The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 5, 475-92.

Heckman, J. (1981). Statistical models for discrete panel data. In C. Manski and D. McFadden (eds.) Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications. pp. 115-78. Cam­bridge, MA: MIT Press.

Heckman, J., and G. Sedlacek (1985). Heterogeneity, aggregation and market wage func­tions: an empirical model of self-selection in the labor market. Journal of Political Economy 93, 1077-125.

Hotz, V. J., and R. A. Miller (1993). Conditional choice probabilities and the estimation of dynamic programming models. Review of Economic Studies 60, 497-530.

Houser, D. (1999). Bayesian analysis of a dynamic, stochastic model of labor supply and saving. Manuscript, University of Arizona.

Keane, M., and K. Wolpin (1994). Solution and estimation of discrete choice dynamic programming models by simulation and interpolation: Monte Carlo Evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 648-72.

Keane, M., and K. Wolpin (1997). The career decisions of young men. Journal of Political Economy 105, 473-522.

Krusell, P., and A. A. Smith (1995). Rules of thumb in macroeconomic equilibrium: a quan­titative analysis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 20, 527-58.

Lancaster, T. (1997). Exact structural inference in optimal job search models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 15, 165-79.

Lerman, S., and C. Manski (1981). On the use of simulated frequencies to approximate choice probabilities. In C. Manski and D. McFadden (eds.) Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications. pp. 305-19. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Manski, C. (1993). Dynamic choice in social settings. Journal of Econometrics 58, 121-36.

McFadden, D. (1989). A method of simulated moments for estimation of discrete response models without numerical integration. Econometrica 57, 995-1026.

Monfort, A., Van Dijk, H., and B. Brown (eds.) (1995). Econometric Inference Using Simula­tion Techniques. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Ltd.

Roy, A. D. (1951). Some thoughts on the distribution of earnings. Oxford Economic Papers 3, 135-46.

Rust, J. (1987). Optimal replacement of GMC bus engines: an empirical model of Harold Zurcher. Econometrica 55, 999-1033.

Rust, J. (1994). Estimation of dynamic structural models, problems and prospects: discrete decision processes. In C. Sims (ed.) Advances in Econometrics, Sixth World Congress Vol. II. pp. 119-70. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Tierney, L. (1994). Markov chains for exploring posterior distributions. Annals of Statistics 22, 1701-32.

Wolpin, K. (1984). An estimable dynamic stochastic model of fertility and child mortality. Journal of Political Economy 92, 852-74.

Zellner, A. (1971). An Introduction to Bayesian Inference in Econometrics. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Добавить комментарий

A COMPANION TO Theoretical Econometrics

Normality tests

Let us now consider the fundamental problem of testing disturbance normality in the context of the linear regression model: Y = Xp + u, (23.12) where Y = (y1, ..., …

Univariate Forecasts

Univariate forecasts are made solely using past observations on the series being forecast. Even if economic theory suggests additional variables that should be useful in forecasting a particular variable, univariate …

Further Research on Cointegration

Although the discussion in the previous sections has been confined to the pos­sibility of cointegration arising from linear combinations of I(1) variables, the literature is currently proceeding in several interesting …

Как с нами связаться:

Украина:
г.Александрия
тел./факс +38 05235  77193 Бухгалтерия

+38 050 457 13 30 — Рашид - продажи новинок
e-mail: msd@msd.com.ua
Схема проезда к производственному офису:
Схема проезда к МСД

Партнеры МСД

Контакты для заказов оборудования:

Внимание! На этом сайте большинство материалов - техническая литература в помощь предпринимателю. Так же большинство производственного оборудования сегодня не актуально. Уточнить можно по почте: Эл. почта: msd@msd.com.ua

+38 050 512 1194 Александр
- телефон для консультаций и заказов спец.оборудования, дробилок, уловителей, дражираторов, гереторных насосов и инженерных решений.