Springer Texts in Business and Economics
Time-Series Analysis
14.1 The AR(1) Model. yt = pyt_i + ©t with |p| <1 and ©t ~ IIN (0, a©2). Also, yo - N (0, o©2/1 - p2).
a. By successive substitution
yt = pyt_i + ©t = p(pyt_2 + ©t_1) + ©t = P2yt_2 + P©t_1 + ©t
= p2(pyt_3 + ©t_2) + p©t_1 + ©t = p3yt_3 + p2 ©t_2 + p©t_1 + ©t
= ••• = pVo c pt 1©i c pt 2©2 C ••• C ©t Then, E(yt) = ptE(yo) = 0 for every t, since E(yo) = E(©t) = 0.
var(yt) = p2tvar(yo) C p2(t 1)var(©i) C p2(t 2)var(©2) C------------------------------------ C var(©t)
If p = 1, then var(yt) = „©2/0 ! 1. Also, if |p| > 1, then 1 — p2 < 0 and var(yt) < 0.
b. The AR(1) series yt has zero mean and constant variance „2 = var(yt), for t = 0, 1 , 2, ... In part (a) we could have stopped the successive substitution at yt_s, this yields yt = psyt_s C pS 1©t_s+1 C • • C©t
Therefore, cov(yt, yt_s) = cov(psyt_s C Ps 1©t_s+1 C • • C©t, yt_s) = psvar(yt_s) = ps„2 which only depends on s the distance between t and t-s. Therefore, the AR(1) series yt is said to be covariance-stationary or weakly stationary.
B. H. Baltagi, Solutions Manual for Econometrics, Springer Texts in Business and Economics, DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-54548-1_14, © Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2015
c. First one generates yo = 0.5 N(0,1)/(1 — p2)1/2 for various values of p. Then yt = pyt_i + et where et ~ IIN(0,0.25) for t = 1,2,.., T.
14.2 The MA(1) Model. yt = et + 0et_1 with et ~ IIN (0, о2)
a. E(yt) = E(et) + 0E(et_1) = 0 for all t. Also,
var(yt) = var(et) + 02var(et_1) = (1 + 02)oe2 for all t.
Therefore, the mean and variance are independent of t.
b. cov(yt, yt—1) = cov(et + 0St_1, St_1 + 0St_2) = 0var(8t_1) = 0oe2
0a©2 when s = 1 0 when s >1
0a©2 when s = 1 0 when s >1
for all t and s, then the MA(1) process is covariance stationary.
c. First one generates et ~ IIN(0,0.25). Then, for various values of 0, one generates yt = et + 0et_1.
14.3
a. The sample autocorrelation function for Income using EViews is as follows:
Correlogram of Income Sample: 1959 2007 Included observations: 49
Partial
Autocorrelation |
Correlation |
AC |
PAC |
Q-Stat |
Prob. |
1 ******* |
|******* 1 |
0.935 |
0.935 |
45.538 |
0 |
1 ******* |
■ 1 ■ 2 |
0.869 |
-0.043 |
85.714 |
0 |
1 ****** |
■ 1 ■ 3 |
0.804 |
-0.031 |
120.81 |
0 |
1 ****** |
■ 1 ■ 4 |
0.737 |
-0.05 |
150.95 |
0 |
1 ***** |
■ 1 ■ 5 |
0.671 |
-0.026 |
176.52 |
0 |
1 ***** |
■ 1 ■ 6 |
0.607 |
-0.026 |
197.93 |
0 |
1**** |
■ 1 ■ 7 |
0.545 |
-0.022 |
215.62 |
0 |
1**** |
■ 1 ■ 8 |
0.484 |
-0.034 |
229.91 |
0 |
1*** |
■ 1 ■ 9 |
0.428 |
-0.006 |
241.33 |
0 |
1*** |
■ 1 ■ 10 |
0.373 |
-0.023 |
250.25 |
0 |
I** |
■ 1 ■ 11 |
0.324 |
0.005 |
257.17 |
0 |
I** |
■ 1 ■ 12 |
0.278 |
-0.022 |
262.37 |
0 |
I** |
■ 1 ■ 13 |
0.232 |
-0.025 |
266.12 |
0 |
■ |*. |
■ 1 ■ 14 |
0.189 |
-0.022 |
268.68 |
0 |
■ |*. |
■ 1 ■ 15 |
0.15 |
-0.009 |
270.33 |
0 |
|*. |
.*| . |
16 |
0.105 |
-0.077 |
271.17 |
0 |
| . |
. | . |
17 |
0.061 |
-0.033 |
271.46 |
0 |
| . |
. | . |
18 |
0.016 |
-0.056 |
271.48 |
0 |
| . |
. | . |
19 |
-0.029 |
-0.038 |
271.56 |
0 |
*| . |
. | . |
20 |
-0.072 |
-0.024 |
272 |
0 |
The sample autocorrelation function for differenced Income is as follows: |
Correlogram of Differenced Income Sample: 1959 2007 Included observations: 48 Partial
b. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic for Income using a constant and linear trend is as follows: |
Null Hypothesis: Y has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
t-Statistic Prob.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -1.843738 0.6677
Test critical values: 1% level -4.161144
5% level -3.506374
10% level -3.183002
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(Y)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1960 2007 Included observations: 48 after adjustments
This does not reject the null hypothesis of unit root for Income. c. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic for differenced Income using a
constant and linear trend is as follows:
Null Hypothesis: D(Y) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
F-statistic 22.58242 Durbin-Watson stat 2.018360 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000
This rejects the null hypothesis of unit root for differenced Income. We conclude that Income is I(1).
d. Let R1 denote the ols residuals from the regression of Consumption on Income and a constant. This tests R1 for unit roots: This ADF includes a constant
Null Hypothesis: R1 has a unit root Exogenous: Constant
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic |
t-Statistic Prob.‘ -1.502798 0.5237 |
Test critical values: 1 % level |
-3.574446 |
5% level |
-2.923780 |
10% level |
-2.599925 |
‘MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(R1)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1960 2007 Included observations: 48 after adjustments
Coefficient |
Std. Error t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
R1(-1) |
-0.094140 |
0.062643 -1.502798 |
0.1397 |
C |
-1.110596 |
26.49763 -0.041913 |
0.9667 |
R-squared |
0.046798 |
Mean dependent var |
0.149870 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.026076 |
S. D. dependent var |
185.9291 |
S. E. of regression |
183.4889 |
Akaike info criterion |
13.30296 |
Sum squared resid |
1548737. |
Schwarz criterion |
13.38093 |
Log likelihood |
-317.2710 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
13.33242 |
F-statistic |
2.258401 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
2.408726 |
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.139726 |
This ADF includes a constant and a linear trend. |
Null Hypothesis: R1 has a unit root Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Lag Length: 1 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
|
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(R1)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1961 2007 Included observations: 47 after adjustments
|
Both ADF tests do not reject the null hypothesis of unit roots in the ols residuals.
f. Correlogram of log(consumption)
Correlogram of log(consumption)
Sample: 1959 2007 Included Observations: 49
Partial
|
For log(consumption), the ADF with a Constant and Linear Trend yields:
Null Hypothesis: LOGC has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
t-Statistic |
Prob.* |
|
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic |
-3.201729 |
0.0965 |
Test critical values: 1% level |
-4.165756 |
|
5% level |
-3.508508 |
|
10% level |
-3.184230 |
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(LOGC)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1961 2007
Included observations: 47 after adjustments
Coefficient |
Std. Error t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
LOGC(-1) |
-0.216769 |
0.067704 -3.201729 |
0.0026 |
D(LOGC(-1)) |
0.447493 |
0.129784 3.447996 |
0.0013 |
C |
1.987148 |
0.614623 3.233118 |
0.0024 |
@TREND(1959) |
0.004925 |
0.001590 3.097180 |
0.0034 |
R-squared |
0.311464 |
Mean dependent var |
0.024014 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.263427 |
S. D. dependent var |
0.015980 |
S. E. of regression |
0.013715 |
Akaike info criterion |
-5.659384 |
Sum squared resid |
0.008088 |
Schwarz criterion |
-5.501924 |
Log likelihood |
136.9955 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
-5.600131 |
F-statistic |
6.483785 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
1.978461 |
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.001019 |
We do not reject the null hypothesis that log(consumption) has unit root at the 5% level, but we do so at the 10% level. For differenced log(consumption), the ADF with a Constant and Linear Trend yields: |
Null Hypothesis: D(LOGC) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
t-Statistic |
Prob.* |
|
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic |
-5.143889 |
0.0006 |
Test critical values: 1 % level |
-4.170583 |
|
5% level |
-3.510740 |
|
10% level |
-3.185512 |
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(LOGC,2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1962 2007
Included observations: 46 after adjustments
Coefficient |
Std. Error t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
D(LOGC(-1)) |
-0.848482 |
0.164950 -5.143889 |
0.0000 |
D(LOGC(-1),2) |
0.253834 |
0.143686 1.766584 |
0.0846 |
C |
0.026204 |
0.006566 3.990611 |
0.0003 |
@TREND(1959) |
-0.000215 |
0.000165 -1.307036 |
0.1983 |
R-squared |
0.403764 |
Mean dependent var |
0.000300 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.361175 |
S. D. dependent var |
0.018320 |
S. E. of regression |
0.014642 |
Akaike info criterion |
-5.526861 |
Sum squared resid |
0.009005 |
Schwarz criterion |
-5.367849 |
Log likelihood |
131.1178 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
-5.467294 |
F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) |
9.480625 0.000066 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
2.028804 |
We do reject the null hypothesis that differenced log(consumption) has unit root at the 5% level. |
Correlogram of log Income Sample: 1959 2007 Included Observations: 49
Autocorrelation |
Partial |
|||||
Correlation |
AC |
PAC |
Q-Stat |
Prob |
||
|******* |
і******* |
1 |
0.935 |
0.935 |
45.507 |
0 |
|******* |
. | . |
2 |
0.867 |
-0.057 |
85.463 |
0 |
|****** |
. | . |
3 |
0.798 |
-0.042 |
120.07 |
0 |
|****** |
. | . |
4 |
0.729 |
-0.041 |
149.58 |
0 |
|***** |
. | . |
5 |
0.661 |
-0.035 |
174.36 |
0 |
|***** |
. | . |
6 |
0.596 |
-0.012 |
194.98 |
0 |
|**** |
. | . |
7 |
0.534 |
-0.016 |
211.96 |
0 |
|**** |
. | . |
8 |
0.475 |
-0.026 |
225.69 |
0 |
1*** |
. | . |
9 |
0.418 |
-0.015 |
236.64 |
0 |
. | . |
10 |
0.365 |
-0.021 |
245.17 |
0 |
|
1** |
. | . |
11 |
0.315 |
-0.009 |
251.7 |
0 |
1** |
. | . |
12 |
0.268 |
-0.023 |
256.54 |
0 |
1** |
. | . |
13 |
0.222 |
-0.023 |
259.97 |
0 |
1* |
. | . |
14 |
0.179 |
-0.017 |
262.26 |
0 |
1* |
. | . |
15 |
0.141 |
0.002 |
263.72 |
0 |
1* |
■*|. |
16 |
0.098 |
-0.079 |
264.44 |
0 |
. | . |
17 |
0.055 |
-0.035 |
264.68 |
0 |
|
. | . |
18 |
0.011 |
-0.043 |
264.69 |
0 |
|
. | . |
19 |
-0.031 |
-0.034 |
264.77 |
0 |
|
| . |
. | . |
20 |
-0.071 |
-0.018 |
265.2 |
0 |
For log(Income), the ADF with a Constant and Linear Trend yields: |
Null Hypothesis: LOGY has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
t-Statistic |
Prob.* |
|
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic |
-1.567210 |
0.7912 |
Test critical values: 1% level |
-4.161144 |
|
5% level |
-3.506374 |
|
10% level |
-3.183002 |
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. |
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(LOGY)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1960 2007 |
||||
Included observations: 48 |
after adjustments |
|||
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
LOGY(-1) |
-0.079684 |
0.050844 |
-1.567210 |
0.1241 |
C |
0.765061 |
0.469055 |
1.631070 |
0.1099 |
@TREND(1959) |
0.001460 |
0.001136 |
1.285021 |
0.2054 |
R-squared |
0.118240 |
Mean dependent var |
0.022569 |
|
Adjusted R-squared |
0.079051 |
S. D. dependent var |
0.016010 |
|
S. E. of regression |
0.015364 |
Akaike info criterion |
-5.453080 |
|
Sum squared resid |
0.010623 |
Schwarz criterion |
-5.336130 |
|
Log likelihood |
133.8739 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
-5.408884 |
|
F-statistic |
3.017149 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
1.746698 |
|
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.058936 |
We do not reject the null hypothesis that log(income) has unit root at the 5% level.
For differenced log(income), the ADF with a Constant and Linear Trend yields:
Null Hypothesis: D(LOGY) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
t-Statistic |
Prob.* |
|
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic |
-6.336919 |
0.0000 |
Test critical values : 1% level |
-4.165756 |
|
5% level |
-3.508508 |
|
10% level |
-3.184230 |
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. |
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(LOGY,2) Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1961 2007 Included observations: 47 after adjustments
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
D(LOGY(-1)) |
-0.924513 |
0.145893 |
-6.336919 |
0.0000 |
C |
0.029916 |
0.006480 |
4.616664 |
0.0000 |
@TREND(1959) |
-0.000347 |
0.000172 |
-2.019494 |
0.0496 |
R-squared |
0.477988 |
Mean dependent var |
0.000278 |
|
Adjusted R-squared |
0.454260 |
S. D. dependent var |
0.020895 |
|
S. E. of regression |
0.015436 |
Akaike info criterion |
-5.442528 |
|
Sum squared resid |
0.010484 |
Schwarz criterion |
-5.324434 |
|
Log likelihood |
130.8994 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
-5.398088 |
|
F-statistic |
20.14464 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
2.057278 |
|
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000001 |
We do reject the null hypothesis that differenced log(income) has unit root at the 5% level.
The OLS regression of log(consumption) on log(income) and a constant yields:
Dependent Variable: LOGC Method: Least Squares
Sample: 1959 2007 Included observations: 49
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
C |
-0.625988 |
0.107332 |
-5.832253 |
0.0000 |
LOGY |
1.053340 |
0.010972 |
95.99861 |
0.0000 |
R-squared |
0.994926 |
Mean dependent var |
9.672434 |
|
Adjusted R-squared |
0.994818 |
S. D. dependent var |
0.335283 |
|
S. E. of regression |
0.024136 |
Akaike info criterion |
-4.570278 |
|
Sum squared resid |
0.027379 |
Schwarz criterion |
-4.493061 |
|
Log likelihood |
113.9718 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
-4.540982 |
|
F-statistic |
9215.733 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
0.205803 |
|
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000000 |
Let R2 denote the ols residuals from the regression of Log(Consumption) on log(Income) and a constant.
This tests R2 for unit roots:
Null Hypothesis: R2 has a unit root Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend Lag Length: 0 (Automatic based on SIC, MAXLAG=10)
t-Statistic |
Prob.* |
|
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic |
-1.898473 |
0.6399 |
Test critical values: 1 % level |
-4.161144 |
|
5% level |
-3.506374 |
|
10% level |
-3.183002 |
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values. |
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation Dependent Variable: D(R2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1960 2007 Included observations: 48 after adjustments
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
R2(-1) |
-0.122648 |
0.064603 |
-1.898473 |
0.0641 |
C |
-0.005115 |
0.003074 |
-1.663739 |
0.1031 |
@TREND(1959) |
0.000201 |
0.000109 |
1.838000 |
0.0727 |
We do not reject the null hypothesis of unit roots in these ols residuals.
Johansen’s Cointegration Tests for Log(consumption) and log(Y)
Sample (adjusted): 1961 2007
Included observations: 47 after adjustments
Trend assumption: Linear deterministic trend
Series: LOGC LOGY
Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 1
Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Trace)
Hypothesized Trace
No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic
None 0.253794 14.26745
At most 1 0.010751 0.508018
Trace test indicates no cointegration at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values
Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Maximum Eigenvalue)
Max-eigenvalue test indicates no cointegration at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values
Both tests indicate no cointegration between Log(consumption) and log(Y) at the 5% level
GARCH(1,1) for Log(consumption) and log(Y)
Dependent Variable: LOGC
Method: ML - ARCH (Marquardt) - Normal distribution
Sample: 1959 2007 Included observations: 49 Convergence achieved after 20 iterations Presample variance: backcast (parameter = 0.7) GARCH = C(3) + C(4)*RESID(-1)"2 + C(5)*GARCH(-1)
Coefficient |
Std. Error |
z-Statistic |
Prob. |
|
C |
-0.712055 |
0.077795 |
-9.152987 |
0.0000 |
LOGY |
1.063091 |
0.007986 |
133.1172 |
0.0000 |
Variance Equation |
||||
C |
0.000127 |
0.000114 |
1.112565 |
0.2659 |
RESID(-1)"2 |
1.332738 |
0.542199 |
2.458025 |
0.0140 |
GARCH(-1) |
-0.195201 |
0.120479 |
-1.620211 |
0.1052 |
R-squared |
0.994060 |
Mean dependent var |
9.672434 |
|
Adjusted R-squared |
0.993521 |
S. D. dependent var |
0.335283 |
|
S. E. of regression |
0.026989 |
Akaike info criterion |
-4.800472 |
|
Sum squared resid |
0.032049 |
Schwarz criterion |
-4.607429 |
|
Log likelihood |
122.6116 |
Hannan-Quinn criter. |
-4.727232 |
|
F-statistic |
1841.004 |
Durbin-Watson stat |
0.178014 |
|
Prob(F-statistic) |
0.000000 |
14.5 Data Description: This data is obtained from the Citibank data base.
Ml: is the seasonally adjusted monetary base. This a monthly average series. We get the quarterly average of M1 by using (M1t + M1t+i + M1t+2)/3. TBILL3: is the T-bill-3 month-rate. This is a monthly series. We
calculate a quarterly average of TBILL3 by using (TBILL3t + TBILL3t+1 + TBILL3t+2)/3. Note that TBILL3 is an annualized rate (per annum).
GNP: This is Quarterly GNP. All series are transformed by taking their natural logarithm.
a. VAR with two lags on each variable
Sample(adjusted): 1959:3 1995:2
Included observations: 144 after adjusting endpoints
Standard errors & t-statistics in parentheses
LNGNP |
LNM1 |
LNTBILL3 |
|
LNGNP(-1) |
1.135719 |
-0.005500 |
1.437376 |
(0.08677) |
(0.07370) |
(1.10780) |
|
(13.0886) |
(-0.07463) |
(1.29751) |
|
LNGNP(-2) |
-0.130393 |
0.037241 |
-1.131462 |
(0.08750) |
(0.07431) |
(1.11705) |
|
(-1.49028) |
(0.50115) |
(-1.01290) |
LNM1(-1) |
0.160798 (0.07628) (2.10804) |
1.508925 (0.06478) (23.2913) |
1.767750 (0.97383) (1.81525) |
LNM1(-2) |
-0.163492 (0.07516) (-2.17535) |
-0.520561 (0.06383) (-8.15515) |
-1.892962 (0.95951) (-1.97284) |
LNTBILL3(-1) |
0.001615 (0.00645) (0.25047) |
-0.036446 (0.00547) (-6.65703) |
1.250074 (0.08230) (15.1901) |
LNTBILL3(-2) |
-0.008933 (0.00646) (-1.38286) |
0.034629 (0.00549) (6.31145) |
-0.328626 (0.08248) (-3.98453) |
C |
-0.011276 (0.07574) (-0.14888) |
-0.179754 (0.06433) (-2.79436) |
-1.656048 (0.96696) (-1.71264) |
R-squared |
0.999256 |
0.999899 |
0.946550 |
Adj. R-squared |
0.999223 |
0.999895 |
0.944209 |
Sum sq. resids |
0.009049 |
0.006527 |
1.474870 |
S. E. equation |
0.008127 |
0.006902 |
0.103757 |
Log likelihood |
492.2698 |
515.7871 |
125.5229 |
Akaike AI C |
-9.577728 |
-9.904358 |
-4.484021 |
Schwarz SC |
-9.433362 |
-9.759992 |
-4.339656 |
Mean dependent |
8.144045 |
5.860579 |
1.715690 |
S. D. dependent |
0.291582 |
0.672211 |
0.439273 |
Determinant Residual Covariance 2.67E-11 Log Likelihood 1355.989
Akaike Information Criteria -24.24959
Schwarz Criteria -24.10523
b. VAR with three lags on each variable
Sample(adjusted): 1959:4 1995:2
Included observations: 143 after adjusting endpoints
Standard errors & t-statistics in parentheses
LNGNP |
LNM1 |
LNTBILL3 |
|
LNGNP(-1) |
1.133814 |
-0.028308 |
1.660761 |
(0.08830) |
(0.07328) |
(1.11241) |
|
(12.8398) |
(-0.38629) |
(1.49295) |
|
LNGNP(-2) |
-0.031988 |
0.103428 |
0.252378 |
(0.13102) |
(0.10873) |
(1.65053) |
|
(-0.24414) |
(0.95122) |
(0.15291) |
LNGNP(-3) |
-0.105146 (0.08774) (-1.19842) |
-0.045414 (0.07281) (-0.62372) |
-1.527252 (1.10526) (-1.38180) |
LNM1(-1) |
0.098732 (0.10276) (0.96081) |
1.375936 (0.08528) (16.1349) |
1.635398 (1.29449) (1.26335) |
LNM1(-2) |
-0.012617 (0.17109) (-0.07375) |
-0.134075 (0.14198) (-0.94432) |
-3.555324 (2.15524) (-1.64962) |
LNM1(-3) |
-0.085778 (0.09254) (-0.92693) |
-0.253402 (0.07680) (-3.29962) |
1.770995 (1.16577) (1.51917) |
LNTBILL3(-1) |
0.001412 (0.00679) (0.20788) |
-0.041461 (0.00564) (-7.35638) |
1.306043 (0.08555) (15.2657) |
LNTBILL3(-2) |
-0.013695 (0.01094) (-1.25180) |
0.039858 (0.00908) (4.38997) |
-0.579077 (0.13782) (-4.20158) |
LNTBILL3(-3) |
0.006468 (0.00761) (0.84990) |
0.000144 (0.00632) (0.02281) |
0.207577 (0.09588) (2.16504) |
C |
0.037812 (0.07842) (0.48217) |
-0.166320 (0.06508) (-2.55566) |
-2.175434 (0.98789) (-2.20210) |
R-squared |
0.999271 |
0.999907 |
0.950041 |
Adj. R-squared |
0.999222 |
0.999901 |
0.946661 |
Sum sq. resids |
0.008622 |
0.005938 |
1.368186 |
S. E. equation |
0.008051 |
0.006682 |
0.101425 |
Log likelihood |
491.8106 |
518.4767 |
129.5215 |
Akaike AIC |
-9.576480 |
-9.949432 |
-4.509499 |
Schwarz SC |
-9.369288 |
-9.742240 |
-4.302307 |
Mean dependent |
8.148050 |
5.866929 |
1.718861 |
S. D. dependent |
0.288606 |
0.670225 |
0.439160 |
Determinant Residual Covariance 2.18E-11 Log Likelihood 1360.953
Akaike Information Criteria -24.40808
Schwarz Criteria -24.20088
d. Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Sample: 1959:1 1995:2 Lags: 3
Obs F-Statistic Probability
LNTBILL3 does not Granger Cause LNM1 143 20.0752 7.8E-11
LNM1 does not Granger Cause LNTBILL3 1.54595 0.20551
e. Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Pairwise Granger Causality Tests Sample: 1959:1 1995:2 Lags: 2
Obs F-Statistic Probability
LNTBILL3 does not Granger Cause LNM1 144 23.0844 2.2E-09
LNM1 does not Granger Cause LNTBILL3 3.99777 0.02051
14.6 The Simple Deterministic Time Trend Model. This is based on Hamilton (1994). yt = a + "t + ut t = 1,... ,T where ut ~ IIN(0, a2).
In vector form, this can be written as y = X® + u, X = [1,t], ® =
a. ®ols = (X'X)-1X'y and ®ols - ® = (X'X)-1X'u Therefore,
1 (T + 1)/2
(T + 1)/2 (T + 1)(2T + 1)/6
Therefore, plim(XjX) diverges as T! 1 and is not a positive definite matrix.
c. Note that
TT
TEi Т^Е t
t=i t=i
TT
T2Et ТзЕt2
L t=1 t=1 .
d. Show that z1 = - E ut ~ N(0, ct2). ut ~ N(0, ct2), so that Eut
VT t=i t=i
N(0,Tct2).
Therefore, —T P ut ~ N (0, - T • Tct2 • —t) = N(0, ct2).
T2
Also, show that z2 = t-t E tut ~ N 0, 6T. • (T + 1)(2T + 1) .
has an asymptotic distribution N(0, ct2Q). Hence, [A 1(X, X)A J] 1 [A-1(X0u)] has an asymptotic distribution N(0,Q-1ct2QQ-1) or N(0, o2Q-1). Thus,
T ((a ols - a)
TPT " ols - " ,
has an asymptotic distribution N(0, o2Q-1). Since "ols has the factor T/T rather than the usual VT, it is said to be superconsistent. This means that not only does ("ols — ") converge to zero in probability limits, but so does T("ols — "). Note that the normality assumption is not needed for this result. Using the central limit theorem, all that is needed is that ut is White noise with finite fourth moments, see Sims et al. (1990) or Hamilton (1994).
Test of Hypothesis with a Deterministic Time Trend Model. This is based on Hamilton (1994).
t
a. Show thatplim s2 = Tzy S(yt — 'ok — "olst)2 = o2. By the law of large
T
Hence, plim s2 = plimTij u2 = var(ut) = ct2
t=1
-y has the same asymptotic N(0,1)
2
s2(1,0)(X'X)-
distribution as t* = VT(a ois_a°). Multiplying both the numerator and
o qll
denominator of ta by VT gives
Now, [P'T, 0] in p can be rewritten as [1,0]A, because [1,0]A = [1,0] f TPT = [PT, 0].
Therefore, ta = ----------------- VT(Sols~a°)------------- r-
s2[1,0]A(X'X)-1A
(aols ao) , *
oVq^ " '
Л/Т (a ols ao)
_WT(Pols - "o)
totic distribution N(0, o2Q-1), so that pT (aols — ao) is asymptotically distributedN(0, o2q11). Thus,
, * Л/Т ('ols ao)
a-~^/qr~
is asymptotically distributed as N(0,1) under the null hypothesis of a = ao. Therefore, both ta and t* have the same asymptotic N(0,1) distribution. c. Similarly, fortesting Ho; " = "o, show that
t" = (" ols — "o)/[s2(0,1)(X0X)-1(0,1)0]1/2
has the same asymptotic N(0,1) distribution as t* = T/T(pols—p^/o^q22. Multiplying both numerator and denominator of tp by T/T we get,
tp = tVT(P ois — po)/[s2(0,TVT)(X'X)—1(0,tVT)']1/2
= tVT(|° ois — Po)/[s2(0,1)A(X, X)_1A(0,1)0]1/2
Now [0,TVT] in tp can be rewritten as [0,1]A because
Therefore, plim tp = TVT (pols — "o) /[o2(0,1)Q“1(0,1),]1/2 = TVT (pols — Po^ /oy^q22- Using plim s2 = o2 and plim A(X0X)_1A = Q_1, we get that plim [s2(0,1)A(X0X)_1A(0,1)0]1/2 = [o2(0,1)Q_1(0,1)0]1/2 = o^q22 where q22 is the (2,2) element of Q_1. Therefore, tp has the same asymptotic distribution as
TVT (pols — p^ /^q22 = tp*
From problem 14.6, part (e), T/T ols — po^ has an asymptotic distribution N(0, o2q22). Therefore, both tp and t* have the same asymptotic N(0,1) distribution - Also, the usual OLS t-tests for a = ao and p = po will give asymptotically valid inference-
14.8 A Random Walk Model. This is based on Fuller (1976) and Hamilton (1994). yt = yt_1 + ut, t = 0,1,.., T where ut ~ IIN(0, o2) and yo = 0.
a. Show that yt = u1 h-------------- hut with E(yt) = 0 and var(yt) = to2. By successive
substitution, we get
yt = yt—1 + ut = yt—2 + ut-1 + ut = •• = yo + u1 + u2 h hut
substituting yo = 0 we get yt = u1 + •• +ut.
Hence, E(yt) = E(u1) + • • +E(ut) = 0
var(yt) = var(u1) + • • +var(ut) = to2
and yt - N(0, to2).
2 1
prj - 222 • T u2 is asymptotically distributed as 2 (x2 - 1).
c. Show that E ^P у2-^ = T(T2-1)o2. Using the results in part (a), we get
yt-1 = yo + u1 + u2 + •• +ut-1
Substituting yo = 0, squaring both sides and taking expected values, we get E (y2-i) = E (u2) C CE (u2-J = (t - 1)ct2 since the ut’s are independent.
Therefore,
E (E y?-t! = X E (yf-x) = E(t - V = T^T2L^-2
U=1
T
where we used the fact that t = T(T C 1)/2 from problem 14.6.
t=i
d. For the AR(1) model, yt = pyt-i C ut, show that OLS estimate of p satisfies
T
From part (b), T;? P yt-1ut has an asymptotic distribution 1 (x2 — 1).
This implies that J2 yt-1ut/o2 converges to an asymptotic distribution of
2 (x? — 1) at the rate of T. Also, from part (c), E ^P y2-1^ = g T(T ^
t=1
to 2 at the rate of T2. One can see that the asymptotic distribution of p when p = 1 is a ratio of a 2 (xf — 1) random variable to a non-standard distribution in the denominator which is beyond the scope of this book, see Hamilton (1994) or Fuller (1976) for further details. The object of this exercise is to show that if p = 1, VT(p — p) is no longer Normal as in the standard stationary least squares regression with |p| < 1. Also, to show that for the non-stationary (random walk) model, p converges at a faster rate (T) than for the stationary case (VT). From part (c) it is clear that one has to divide the denominator of p by T2 rather than T to get a convergent distribution.
14.9 Cointegration Example
and
, -------------- Ut — ------------ V
(' - P) t (' - P)t (' - P)
In this case, ut is I(0) and vt is I(1). Therefore both Yt and Ct are I(1). Note
that there are no excluded exogenous variables in (14.13) and (14.14) and only one right hand side endogenous variable in each equation. Hence both equations are unidentified by the order condition of identification. However, a linear combination of the two structural equations will have a mongrel disturbance term that is neither AR(1) nor random walk. Hence, both equations are identified. If p = 1, then both u, and v, are random walks and the mongrel disturbance is also a random walk. Therefore, the system is unidentified. In such a case, there is no cointegrating relationship between Ct and Yt. Let (с' - yY,) be another cointegrating relationship, then subtracting it from the first cointegrating relationship, one gets (y - P)Yt which should be I(0). Since Y' is I(1), this can only happen if y = P. Differencing both equations in (14.13) and (14.14) we get
Ac, - pAY' = Au, = (p - 1)u,-i + ©, = ©, + (p - 1)(C'_i - PY'_i)
= s, + (p - 1)C'-1 - P(p - 1)Y'-1
and AC, - aAY, = Av, = q,. Writing them as a VAR, we get (14.17)
"1 - p" |
ac, |
"s, + (p - 1)C'-1 - "(p - 1)Y'-1_ |
|
1 -“_ |
ay, |
q, |
Post-multiplying by the inverse of the first matrix, we get |
ac, |
= |
1 Ї |
1---- CD. 3 1 1___ |
"s, + (p - 1)C'-1 - "(p - 1)Y'-1_ |
ay, |
P -') |
-1 1 |
-aet - a(p - 1)Ct_і + a"(p - 1)Yt_i +
—©t — (p — 1)Ct-i + "(p — 1)Yt-i + ht
where ht and gt are linear combinations of et and rp. This is Eq. (14.18). This
8 = (p — 1)/(" — a) and Zt = Ct — "Yt.
These are Eqs. (14.19) and (14.20). This is the Error-Correction Model (ECM) representation of the original model. Zt-1 is the error correction term. It represents a disequilibrium term showing the departure from long - run equilibrium. Note that if p = 1, then 8 = 0 and Zt-1 drops from both ECM equations.
T T
CtYt Ytut
b. "ols = " C tD1
T
Since ut is I(0) if p ф 1 and Yt is I(1), we have plim p Yt2/T2 is O(1),
t=1
T
while plimp; Ytut/T is O(1). Hence T("ols — ") is O(1) or ("ols — ") is O(T).
t=1
References
Fuller, W. A. (1976), Introduction to Statistical Time Series (John Wiley and Sons: New York).
Hamilton, J. D. (1994), Time Series Analysis (Princeton University Press: Princeton, New Jersey).
P X'/o?] [POA)] - [p( Vo? r
b. From the regression equation Y, = a C "X, C u, one can multiply by w,*
and sum to get P w*Y, = a P w* C " P w*X, C P w*u,. Now divide
i= 1 i i= 1 i i= 1 i i= 1 i n
by w* and use the definitions of Y* and X* to get Y* = a C "X* C u*
i=1 i
nn
where u * = w*u, w*.
i=1 i i=1 i
P wi* (Xi — X*)2
i=1
_ 1 P wi* (Xi — X*)2
i=1
where the third equality uses the fact that the ui’s are not serially correlated and heteroskedastic and the fourth equality uses the fact that w* = (t/o2).