THE ECONOMETRICS OF MACROECONOMIC MODELLING

The dynamic wage-price model

When modelling the short-run relationships we impose the estimated steady state from (9.3) to (9.4) on a subsystem for {Awt, Apt} conditional on {Aat, Ayt, Aut-1, Apit, At1t, At3t} with all variables entering with two additional lags. In addition to energy prices Apet, we augment the system with {Aht, Wdumt, Pdumt} to capture short-run effects. Seasonalt is a centred seasonal dummy. The diagnostics of the unrestricted I(0) system are reported in the upper part of Table 9.2.

The short-run model is derived general to specific by deleting insignifi­cant terms, establishing a parsimonious statistical representation of the data in I(0)-space, following Hendry and Mizon (1993) and is found below:

Awt = -0.124+ 0.809Apt - 0.511Aht + 0.081Aat (0.017) (0.109) (0.123) (0.017)

— 0.163 (wt-1 — pt-1 — at-1 + 0.1ut_2) + 0.024 Seasonal^2 (0.021) (0.002)

— 0.020Wdumt + 0.023 Pdumt (9.5)

(0.003) (0.004)

a = 0.0089.

Table 9.2

Diagnostics for the unrestricted I(0) wage-price
system and the model

Unrestricted I(0) system 52 parameters

Far(! - 5) (20,154) 0.68[0.85]

Molality (4) 4.39[0.36]

FHETx2 (141,114) 0.81[0.88]

Final model

19 parameters

Xoveridentification (33) 33.72[0.43]

FAr(i-5) (20,188) 1.45[0.10]

xnormaiity (4) 6.82[0.15]

FHETx2 (141,165) 1.23[0.10]

Note: References: overidentification test (Anderson and Rubin 1949, 1950; Koopmans et al. 1950; Sargan 1988), AR-test (Godfrey 1978;

Doornik 1996), Normality test (Doornik and Hansen 1994), and Heteroskedasticity test (White 1980; Doornik 1996). The numbers in [..] are p-values.

The sample is 1972(4)-2001(1), 114 observations.

Apt = 0.006 + 0.141Awt + 0.100Awt_i + 0.165Apt_2 - 0.015Aat (0.001) (0.026) (0.021) (0.048) (0.006)

+ 0.028Ayt_ 1 + 0.046Ayt_ 2 + 0.026Apit + 0.042Apet (0.012) (0.012) (0.008) (0.007)

- 0.055 (pt-з - 0.7(wt-2 +11t-i - a—) - 0.3pi—i - 0.5f3—i) (0.006)

- 0.013 Pdumt (9.6) (0.001) t

a = 0.0031

T = 1972(4)-2001(1) = 114.

The lower part of Table 9.2 contains diagnostics for the final model. In particular, we note the insignificance of x2veridentification (33), which shows that the model reduction restrictions are supported by the data.

The wage growth equation implies that a one percentage point increase in the rate of inflation raises wage growth by 0.8 percentage point. The discretionary variables for incomes policies (Wdumt) and for price controls (Pdumt) are also significant. Hence, discretionary policies have clearly

succeeded in affecting consumer real wage growth over the sample period. The equilibrium-correction term is highly significant, as expected. Finally, the change in normal working-time Aht enters the wage equation with a negative coefficient, as expected. In addition to equilibrium-correction and the dummies representing incomes policy, price inflation is significantly influenced by wage growth and output growth (the output gap), together with effects from import prices and energy prices—as predicted by the theoretical model.

The question whether wage-price systems like ours imply a NAIRU prop­erty hinges on the detailed restrictions on the short-run dynamics. A necessary condition for a NAIRU is that wage growth is homogenous with respect to the change in producer prices, Aqt. Using, Apt = (1 — 4>)Aqt + 4>Apit, and since Apit does not enter the wage equation, it is clear that a homogeneity restriction does not hold in the wage growth equation (9.5): using the maintained value of ф = 0.3 from (9.4) the implied wage elasticity with respect to the change in producer prices, Aqt is 0.56. The wage equation therefore implies that we do not have a NAIRU model. Hence, the conventional Phillips curve NAIRU, for example, does not correspond to the eventual steady-state rate of unem­ployment implied by the larger model obtained by grafting the wage and price equations in a larger system of equations.

image182 image183

The model has constant parameters, as shown in Figure 9.3, which contains the one-step residuals and recursive Chow-tests for the model. Finally, the lower left panel of Figure 9.3 shows that the model parsimoniously encompasses the

Figure 9.3. Recursive stability tests for the wage-price model. The upper
panels show recursive residuals for the model. The lower panels show recursive
encompassing tests (left) and recursive Chow tests (right)

system at every sample size. As noted in the introduction, improperly modelled expectations in the dynamic simultaneous equations model could cause the model’s parameters to change when policies change, generating misleading policy simulations, as emphasised by Lucas (1976). However, as Figure 9.3 shows, there is no evidence of any mis-specified expectations mechanisms.

Добавить комментарий

THE ECONOMETRICS OF MACROECONOMIC MODELLING

Inflation equations derived from the P*-model

The P*-model is presented in Section 8.5.4. The basic variables of the model are calculated in much the same way for Norway as for the Euro area in the previous …

Forecast comparisons

Both models condition upon the rate of unemployment ut, average labour productivity at, import prices pit, and GDP mainland output yt. In order to investigate the dynamic forecasting properties we …

The NPCM in Norway

Consider the NPCM (with forward term only) estimated on quarterly Norwegian data[65]: Apt = 1.06 Apt+1 + 0.01 wst + 0.04 Apit + dummies (7.21) (0.11) (0.02) (0.02) x2(10) = …

Как с нами связаться:

Украина:
г.Александрия
тел./факс +38 05235  77193 Бухгалтерия

+38 050 457 13 30 — Рашид - продажи новинок
e-mail: msd@msd.com.ua
Схема проезда к производственному офису:
Схема проезда к МСД

Партнеры МСД

Контакты для заказов оборудования:

Внимание! На этом сайте большинство материалов - техническая литература в помощь предпринимателю. Так же большинство производственного оборудования сегодня не актуально. Уточнить можно по почте: Эл. почта: msd@msd.com.ua

+38 050 512 1194 Александр
- телефон для консультаций и заказов спец.оборудования, дробилок, уловителей, дражираторов, гереторных насосов и инженерных решений.