THE ECONOMETRICS OF MACROECONOMIC MODELLING

Role of economic theory in macroeconometrics

The Cowles Commission research agenda focused on simultaneous equation models (SEMs) and put much weight on the issue of identification. In dealing with these issues, economic theory plays an important part. The prominent representative of this tradition, Lawrence Klein, writes in a very readable survey of the interaction between statistics and economics in the context of macro­econometric modelling (Klein 1988) that the model building approach can be contrasted to pure statistical analysis, which is empirical and not so closely related to received economic theory as is model building.

Still, it is on this score the traditional macroeconomic model building has come under attack (see Favero 2001). Whereas the LSE methodology largely ascribes the failure of those early macroeconomic models to missing dynamics or model mis-specification (omitted energy price effects), other critiques like Robert Lucas and Christopher Sims have claimed that the cause is rather that they had a weak theoretical basis. The Lucas critique (see, for example, Lucas 1976) claims that the failure of conditional models is caused by regime shifts, as a result of policy changes and shifts in expectations. The critique carries over to SEMs if expectations are non-modelled. On the other hand, Sims (1980) argued that SEMs embodied ‘incredible’ identifying restrictions: the restric­tions needed to claim exogeneity for certain variables would not be valid in an environment where agents optimise intertemporally.

Sims instead advocated the use of a low-order vector autoregression to ana­lyse economic time-series. This approach appeared to have the advantage that it did not depend on an ‘arbitrary’ division between exogenous and endogenous variables and also did not require ‘incredible’ identifying restrictions. Instead Sims introduced identifying restrictions on the error structure of the model, and this approach has been criticised for being equally arbitrary. Later devel­opments have led to structural VAR models in which cointegration defines long-run relationships between non-stationary variables and where exogenous variables are reintroduced (see Pesaran and Smith 1998 for a survey in which they reanalyse an early model by King et al. 1991).[7]

Ever since the Keynes-Tinbergen controversy (see Morgan 1990 and Hendry and Morgan 1995), the role of theory in model specification has represented a major controversy in econometrics (cf. Granger 1990, 1999 for recent surveys). At one end of the theory-empiricism line we have theory-driven models that take the received theory for granted, and do not test it. Prominent examples are the general equilibrium models, dubbed real business cycle models, that have gained a dominating position in academia (see, for example, Kydland and Prescott 1991). There is also a new breed of macroeconometric mod­els which assume intertemporally optimising agents endowed with rational forward-looking expectations, leading to a set of Euler equations (see Poloz et al. 1994, Willman et al. 2000, Hunt et al. 2000, and Nilsson 2002 for models from the central banks of Canada, Finland, New Zealand, and Sweden, respec­tively). At another extreme we have data based VAR models which initially were statistical devices that made only minimal use of economic theory. As noted above, in the less extreme case of structural VARs, theory restrictions can be imposed as testable cointegrating relationships in levels or they can be imposed on the error structure of the model.

The approach we are advocating has much in common with the LSE methodology referred to above, and it focuses on evaluation as recommended in Granger (1999). It represents a compromise between data based (purely stat­istical) models and economic theory: on the one hand learning from the process of trying to take serious account of the data, while on the other hand avoiding making strong theoretical assumptions—needed to make theories ‘complete’— which may not make much sense empirically, that is, that are not supported by the data.[8] Moreover, there are common-sense arguments in favour of not adopt­ing a theory-driven model as a basis for policy decisions, which indeed affect reality, until it has gained convincing empirical support (see Granger 1992).

Добавить комментарий

THE ECONOMETRICS OF MACROECONOMIC MODELLING

Inflation equations derived from the P*-model

The P*-model is presented in Section 8.5.4. The basic variables of the model are calculated in much the same way for Norway as for the Euro area in the previous …

Forecast comparisons

Both models condition upon the rate of unemployment ut, average labour productivity at, import prices pit, and GDP mainland output yt. In order to investigate the dynamic forecasting properties we …

The NPCM in Norway

Consider the NPCM (with forward term only) estimated on quarterly Norwegian data[65]: Apt = 1.06 Apt+1 + 0.01 wst + 0.04 Apit + dummies (7.21) (0.11) (0.02) (0.02) x2(10) = …

Как с нами связаться:

Украина:
г.Александрия
тел./факс +38 05235  77193 Бухгалтерия

+38 050 457 13 30 — Рашид - продажи новинок
e-mail: msd@msd.com.ua
Схема проезда к производственному офису:
Схема проезда к МСД

Партнеры МСД

Контакты для заказов оборудования:

Внимание! На этом сайте большинство материалов - техническая литература в помощь предпринимателю. Так же большинство производственного оборудования сегодня не актуально. Уточнить можно по почте: Эл. почта: msd@msd.com.ua

+38 050 512 1194 Александр
- телефон для консультаций и заказов спец.оборудования, дробилок, уловителей, дражираторов, гереторных насосов и инженерных решений.