Advanced Econometrics Takeshi Amemiya

Nonstationary Models

So far we have assumed X)k(t) = Ajfc for all t (constant hazard rate). Now we shall remove this assumption. Such models are called nonstationary or semi - Markov.

Suppose a typical individual stayed in state yin period (0, t) and then moved to state к in period (t, t + AO - We call this event A and derive its probability P(A), generalizing (11.2.2) and (11.2.3). Defining m = t/At and using log (1 — є) = —є for small e, we obtain for sufficiently large m

(11.2.50)

image867The likelihood function of this individual is the last expression in (11.2.50) except for t/m.

Let us obtain the likelihood function of the same event history we consid­ered in the discussion preceding (11.2.4). The likelihood function now be­comes

image868

image869

(11.2.51)

As in (11.2.4), A31 should be changed to A3 if the individual is only observed to leave state 3, and A31 should be dropped if right-censoring occurs at that time.

We shall concentrate on the transition from state 1 to state 2 and write A,2(t) simply as A(t), as we did earlier. The distribution function of duration under a nonstationary model is given by

image870(11.2.52)

which is reduced to (11.2.6) if A(r) = A. The density function is given by

Подпись: f(t) = A(/) exp Г- [Подпись: L Joimage873(11.2.53)

The likelihood function again can be written in the form of (11.2.10) or

(11.2.11) , depending on whether right-censoring is absent or present.

Thus we see that there is no problem in writing down the likelihood func­tion. The problem, of course, is how to estimate the parameters. Suppose we specify A'(0 generally as

image395

To evaluate foA'(z) dz, which appears in the likelihood function, a researcher must specify x„ precisely as a continuous function of t—not an easy thing to do in practice. We shall discuss several empirical articles and shall see how these articles deal with the problem of nonstationarity, as well as with other problems that may arise in empirical work.

Model of Tuma. Tuma (1976) analyzed the duration of employment at a particular job. The rth individual’s hazard rate at time t is specified as

Xi{t) = P'xi + Oixt + ot2t2, (11.2.55)

where x, is a vector of socioeconomic characteristics of the rth individual.7 The parameter values are assumed to be such that the hazard rate is nonnegative over a relevant range of t. Because of the simple form of the hazard rate, it can easily be integrated to yield

J A‘(z) dz = fi'Xi t + ^-fi + ^-t3. (11.2.56)

Some people terminate their employment during the sample period, but some remain in their jobs at the end of the sample period (right-censoring). There­fore Tuma’s likelihood function is precisely in the form of (11.2.11).

Model of Tuma, Hannan, and Groeneveld. Tuma, Hannan, and Groene - veld (1979) studied the duration of marriage. They handled nonstationarity by dividing the sample period into four subperiods and assuming that the hazard rate remains constant within each subperiod but varies across different subperiods. More specifically, they specified

A'(0 = #x, for / Є Tp, p= 1,2,3,4, (11.2.57)

where Tp is the pth subperiod. This kind of a discrete change in the hazard rate creates no real problem. Suppose that the event history of an individual consists of a single completed spell of duration t and that during this period a constant hazard rate A(l) holds from time 0 to time т and another constant rate A(2) holds from time т to time t. Then this individual’s likelihood function is given by

L = е-*1*е-*2Х‘-Ч(2). (11.2.58)

Model of Lancaster. Lancaster (1979) was concerned with unemployment duration and questioned the assumption of a constant hazard rate. Although a simple search theory may indicate an increasing hazard rate, it is not clear from economic theory alone whether we should expect a constant, decreasing,
or increasing hazard rate for unemployment spells. Lancaster used a Weibull distribution, which leads to a nonconstant hazard rate. The Weibull distribu­tion is defined by

F(t) = 1 - exp (—A/“). (11.2.59)

If a = 1,(11.2.59) is reduced to the exponential distribution considered in the preceding subsections. Its density is given by

fit) = Aat®-1 exp (—Яг®) (11.2.60)

and its hazard rate by

Aft) = { (11.2.61)

Whether a is greater than 1 or not determines whether the hazard rate is increasing or not, as is shown in the following correspondence:

Подпись:Подпись: (11.2.62)(increasing hazard rate) (constant hazard rate) (decreasing hazard rate).

Lancaster specified the z'th person’s hazard rate as

A'(0 = a/®"1 exp ifi'xt), (11.2.63)

where x, is a vector of the z'th person’s characteristics. His ML estimate of a turned out to be 0.77, a result indicating a decreasing hazard rate. However, Lancaster reported an interesting finding: His estimate of a increases as he included more exogenous variables in the model. This result indicates that the decreasing hazard rate implied by his first estimate was at least partly due to the heterogeneity caused by the initially omitted exogenous variables rather than true duration dependence.

Because it may not be possible to include all the relevant exogenous vari­ables, Lancaster considered an alternative specification for the hazard rate

nt) = vtm, (11.2.64)

where X‘(t) is as given in (11.2.63) and vt is an unobservable random variable independently and identically distributed as Gamma(l, <r2). The random
variable vt may be regarded as a proxy for all the unobservable exogenous variables. By (11.2.52) we have (suppressing i)

F{tv) = 1 - exp [-uA(r)], (11.2.65)

where A(/) = Io^(z) dz. Taking the expectation of (11.2.65) yields

F*(t) ■ EvF(tv) = 1 - [1 + (11.2.66)

Therefore, using (11.2.8), we obtain

A*(/) = A(r)[l + (11.2.67)

= A(1)[1-F*(r.

Because [1 — F*(t)]a2 is a decreasing function of t, (11.2.67) shows that the heterogeneity adds a tendency for a decreasing hazard rate. Under this new model (with a2 as an additional unknown parameter), Lancaster finds the MLE of a to be 0.9. Thus he argues that a decreasing hazard rate in his model is caused more by heterogeneity than true duration dependence.

Model of Heckman and Borjas. In their article, which is also concerned with unemployment duration, Heckman and Borjas (1980) introduced an­other source of variability of A in addition to the Weibull specification and heterogeneity. In their model, A also varies with spells. Let / denote the /th unemployment spell the /th individual experiences. Then Heckman and Borjas specify the hazard rate as

A<;(/) = a/"-1 exp ()S/X|7 + v^, (11.2.68)

where v, is unobservable and therefore should be integrated out to obtain the marginal distribution function of duration.8

Model of Flinn and Heckman. In a study of unemployment duration, Flinn and Heckman (1982) generalized (11.2.68) further as

A"(/) = exp |#Xtf(0 + cfii + у і 1 ^ 1 + y2 ** • (П -2.69)

The function (tk — 1 )/A is the Box-Cox transformation (see Section 8.1.2) and approaches log t as A approaches 0. Therefore putting A, = 0 and y2 = 0 in (11.2.69) reduces it to a Weibull model. Note that x(/is assumed to depend on t in (11.2.69). Flinn and Heckman assumed that changes in xu(t) occurred only at the beginning of a month and that the levels were constant throughout the month. The authors devised an efficient computation algorithm for handling
the heterogeneity correlated across spells and the exogenous variables varying with time.

Добавить комментарий

Advanced Econometrics Takeshi Amemiya

Nonlinear Limited Information Maximum Likelihood Estimator

In the preceding section we assumed the model (8.1.1) without specifying the model for Y( or assuming the normality of u, and derived the asymptotic distribution of the class of …

Results of Cosslett: Part II

Cosslett (1981b) summarized results obtained elsewhere, especially from his earlier papers (Cosslett, 1978, 1981a). He also included a numerical evalua­tion of the asymptotic bias and variance of various estimators. We …

Other Examples of Type 3 Tobit Models

Roberts, Maddala, and Enholm (1978) estimated two types of simultaneous equations Tobit models to explain how utility rates are determined. One of their models has a reduced form that is …

Как с нами связаться:

Украина:
г.Александрия
тел./факс +38 05235  77193 Бухгалтерия

+38 050 457 13 30 — Рашид - продажи новинок
e-mail: msd@msd.com.ua
Схема проезда к производственному офису:
Схема проезда к МСД

Партнеры МСД

Контакты для заказов оборудования:

Внимание! На этом сайте большинство материалов - техническая литература в помощь предпринимателю. Так же большинство производственного оборудования сегодня не актуально. Уточнить можно по почте: Эл. почта: msd@msd.com.ua

+38 050 512 1194 Александр
- телефон для консультаций и заказов спец.оборудования, дробилок, уловителей, дражираторов, гереторных насосов и инженерных решений.